Second Annual Conference Rome, October 20th and 21st 2006 LUISS Guido Carli SIDE Working Papers Second Annual Conference - 2006 ENRICO LEONARDO CAMILLI Towards a financial regulatory network in the Italian saving law 262/05: the case of allocation of competences on stability and antitrust Towards a financial regulatory network in the Italian saving law 262/05: the case of allocation of competences on stability and antitrust Enrico Leonardo Camilli∗ ABSTRACT The recent reform on the allocation of regulatory and supervisory competences endeavoured by law 262/05 aims at building a financial regulatory network, where each authority is appointed with a specific function. From an institutional point of view, in the building process of the network two major aspects deserve specific attention, the homogeneization of procedural aspects and the mechanisms to ensure coordination between authorities. Indeed, in a multi-peaks model of allocation of functions (Di Giorgio – Di Noia, 1999), overlapping of different competences is a likely event, as it happens in the merger scrutiny, where both antitrust and stability assessment are carried out. If one of the authorities of the network enjoys a substantially different degree of freedom, a natural leader of the network will come out, and it may be able to enforce an increased level of discretion, which may not be explicitly provided for in the law. The former competence of Banca d’Italia (BI) on both antitrust and supervisory controls may have favoured this role of BI; furthermore, the procedural framework of BI acting a supervisor, as shaped by the TUB and the Handbook, shows some substantial differences compared to the accountability arrangements characterizing the enforcement of antitrust rules. On the other side, within a functional model, the coordination within the network becomes crucial. The paper tries to ascertain how the new saving law (l. 262/05) and the likely future changes proposed by the government may have addressed these aspects. INTRODUCTION The fear of a conflict in the banking sector between the public interest of stability on one side and competition on the other has extensively influenced the structure of competences between antitrust law and banking law. Actually, before the Banking Law, D. Lgs. 385/1993 (s.c. TUB), the entrepreneurial nature of the banking firm was itself contested, since the public interest features of banking were deemed to be prevalent in shaping the nature of bank activity1. This latter vision supported a PhD Law and Economics, LUISS University, Rome, email: [email protected]. I’m grateful to the useful comments made by Prof. M. Clarich. The usual disclaimers apply. 1 On the general category of public interest service in the Italian doctrine see U. POTOTSCHNIG, I pubblici servizi, Padova, 1964. For the qualification of banking within this category, see G. VIGNOCCHI, Aspetti pubblicistici del credito, in Rivista trimestrale di diritto pubblico, 1961, 575. The Supreme Italian Court too used to support this view, see Cass. Sez. Un., 10th of October 1981, n. 10467, in Foro it., 1981, II, 553. ∗ 1 financial regulation style based on a comprehensive and pervasive scrutiny on the overall firm’s operations, backed by the wide discretion the 1936 Banking Law left to the Central Bank in arranging the regulatory framework. Obviously such a regulatory regime was at odd with the possibility itself of a competition among firms and actually most of the Italian banking sector was owned by public bodies. The attribution of the financial supervision to the Central Bank was the natural consequence of its macroeconomic role with regard to the monetary policy. In the 80’s the effect of European Community directives on banking law harmonization forced the Italian legislator to major changes on the features of regulatory intervention, first of all by recognizing the entrepreneurial nature of the banking firm2. From a control involving each act of the firm’s business, the supervision focused on the maintenance of given ratios between the different components of the bank balance sheet, according to the prudential supervision paradigm. The 1993 TUB resumed the change of legislator’s approach on banking. The turning point of the TUB was supported by the different attitude of the economic thought with regard to the relationship between competition and stability. The guarantee of free competition has not been anymore considered per se detrimental for the maintenance of the macroeconomic stability of banking sector3. On the contrary in the long term increased efficiency due to competition, backed by a coherent prudential supervision, may reduce instability risks, by expelling the most inefficient firms that could represent the weak elements in guaranteeing the stability of the overall banking system. The supervision obviously does not loose its pivotal role, but it is focused on a constant monitoring of financial healthy of the financial firms in order to forestall instability risks and to minimize the external costs due to the gradual selection of the most efficient firms4. Coherently, art. 5 of TUB lists both the guarantee of stability and the guarantee of competitiveness as the objectives of banking legislation, according to which the supervision activity of the Central Bank has to be carried out. Actually the breakthrough of the TUB was preceded by the Italian antitrust law, n. 287/90, that contained an explicit provision involving the application of general antitrust rules in banking, at art. 205. The acknowledgement of the entrepreneurial nature of the banking firm was implied in the application of the ordinary antitrust rules, but the allocation of competences between the general antitrust authority (AGCM) and the supervision authority (the Central Bank, BI) was still influenced by the previous regulatory framework, which relied upon the planning role of the Central Bank. In fact, both the application of the prohibition of anti-competitive agreements, of abuses of dominant position and the merger scrutiny used to be carried out by BI up to the law 2 Art. 10 TUB. Competition in banking may have ambivalent effects on stability, i.e. on the likelihood of bank failures having external effects on the whole banking system; for an accurate survey see B. M. PARIGI, La concorrenza nel settore bancario: una rassegna della letteratura, and E. CARLETTI, Concorrenza, regolamentazione e stabilità, in M. POLO (eds), Industria bancaria e concorrenza, 2000, Bologna, 4 Cfr E. CARLETTI – RL HARTMANN, Competition and stability: what’s special about banking?, in European Central Bank Working Paper Series n. 146, 2002; D. LLEWELLYN, The economic rationale for financial regulation, in Financial Services Authorities Occasional Paper Series n. 1, 1999, 46-47. 5 At European level the full application of antitrust rules to banks was already recognized since the famous Zuchner decision, ECJ, 14th of July 1981, Case C-172/80. 3 2 262/05, while the AGCM was appointed with a mandatory but non binding advisory function. According to the system in place up to last December, the AGCM was asked to issue its advice, within 30 days, according to the information supplied by the Central Bank. Actually the access to the secreted information held by BI on the basis of its supervision role was excluded for AGCM by the law, since according to art. 7 of the 1993 Banking Law the AGCM was not included among the authorities allowed to share the information held by BI. Although this latter aspect made more difficult an independent evaluation of the operation, some discrepancies between the BI final decisions and the AGCM advises happened to be (infra). Only the decision making power involving the accordance of exemptions from the prohibition of anticompetitive agreement was shared by both the AGCM and the BI. Another aspect of the 1990 law was the introduction of some provisions aimed at limiting the possible conflicts of interests between bank and industry, at art. 27 and ff. The inclusion of the mentioned rules in antitrust law was significant, since it was acknowledged the possible negative impact on competition of vertical integration between banks and financed firms, besides the likely stability concerns. In 1993 the TUB changed perspective and underlined the stability reasons as the bulk of the discipline, by repealing the rules in the antitrust law and including them in the Banking Law. Up to early 90’s the division of competences for special sectors recently liberalized (like telecommunications, television, banking) appeared to be inspired by a sector allocation principle, and the banking sector did not represent an exception. The sector specific regulator was competent for the application of both sector specific regulation and antitrust rules. However, as soon as the liberalization process went on, the principle of allocation of competences by means of the objectives of regulation took place, thus the AGCM got the general competences for the application of antitrust rules in every sector. In this new framework banking represented the sole exception since 1997, notwithstanding the increasing integration between banking and non-banking financial markets already posed serious problems in defining the competent authority for the application of antitrust rules in mixed markets, i.e. involving banking and nonbanking (financial) operators6. 6 The wording of art. 20 of the Antitrust law actually recalled an allocation criterion based on the subjects involved in the operation (“Aziende ed istituti di credito”), rather that on the markets involved. Such a wording of the article was justified on the basis of the legislative framework in 1990, when banks were allowed to carry out only banking activities, see A. PATRONI GRIFFI, Antitrust e concentrazioni bancarie, in Giurisprudenza commerciale, 1996, 400. However the legislative decree 481/1992 (and afterwards the TUB) modified this aspect, leaving the banks free to carry out other financial activities. As a consequence the terms banks and banking activity do not overlap anymore, thus the problem of the competence for mixed operations (i.e. involving banks and non banking operators or having effect on other non-banking activities) came up. The Italian Supreme Administrative Court finally opted for a restrictive interpretation of the BI competence, limiting it only for operations (mergers, agreements, abuses) involving banks and having effects only on banking activities, see Consiglio di Stato, sez. VI, 16th of October 2002, n. 5640, AGCM v. Assicurazioni Generali, Unicredito, al. in Giornale di diritto amministrativo, 2003, 255, with a comment by M. RAMAJOLI. 3 Several reasons were put forward in order to support the view according to which the appointment of BI as general sector regulator: the cost advantages for the undertakings stemming from a one stop shop principle; the informational advantages of BI thanks to the duty of the banks to provide on a regular basis business information to BI within the regulatory framework on stability; the possibility for the sector regulator to balance stability reasons vis à vis antitrust ones in assessing the cases that may have both stability and competitive effects. Although the antitrust law did not provide the ground for a differentiated application of antitrust rule7, the contemporary assessment of competitive and stability profiles of the operations, in fact, naturally led to that outcome. That is true especially for operations that showed the strongest interrelations between the two profiles, like merger review, where both antitrust powers according to art. 20 l. 287/90 and supervision on stability according to art. 19, 53, 57 TUB were carried out by the same authority. With specific regard to the substantial issues of this scrutiny, it can be reminded the different attitude of AGCM and BI both on the definition of the relevant market8, on the role of potential competition9 and on the conditions to be imposed in order to authorize the acquisition. On the latter point, BI showed a preference towards behavioural conditions, whereas the AGCM strongly supported the adoption of structural measures in its advises 10. Actually the former may have a rather different competitive impact: first of all their fulfilment is much more difficult to ascertain; secondly, they may ease the establishment of collusive equilibriums between the local dominant firm and the competitors11. Furthermore, among the structural measures a different competitive impact stems from the obligation to close branches and the obligation to sell them, especially if the authorization requires transferring them to serious potential competitors. In fact the recent attitude of BI on that point is quite ambiguous: in the Banco di Sicila/Sicilcassa12 case some commentators welcomed the increased attention of BI towards structural measures; however, besides the fact that often the structural measures were imposed together with behavioural measures13, BI kept using behavioural measures extensively and mainly against the AGCM advises14. 7 Unless for art. 20 par.5 on the exemption for anticompetitive agreement. Partially solved with the definition of the geographical extension and of a common threshold to be followed in order to open the phase II of the merger review, see the BI-AGCM Agreement, 4th of March 1996, in Bollettino dell’Autorità Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato, 10/96, point 3. 9 See Banca delle Marche/Cassa di risparmio di Loreto/Mediocredito fondiario Centroitalia, BI, provv. n. 20, 18th of March 1997 and AGCM advise, 27th of February. 10 This different approach is underlined by P.L. PARCU, Commento, in M. POLO (eds), Industria bancaria e concorrenza, Bologna, 2000, 378 and F. DENOZZA – NOZZTABILINI, Rapporti e possibili conflitti tra le autorità preposte all’applicazione della normativa sulla concorrenza con riferimento al settore bancario, in ibidem, 409, with specific reference to the 1997 Cariplo/Carinord Holding case; a similar reasoning can be applied to the Banca delle Marche case, above. 11 See AGCM, advise n. 5657, 29th of January 1998. 12 See BI, provv. n. 22, 3rd of April 1998. 13 See Banca Carige/Cassa di risparmio di Genova e Imperia/Cassa di risparmio di Savona case, BI provv. n. 32, 8th of March 2000, San Paolo – IMI /Banco di Napoli case, BI provv. n. 36 19th of January 2001 14 See BI provv. n. 43, 6th of August 2002 IntesaBci/Cassa di risparmio di Terni e Narni, and BI provv. n. 40 29th of May 2002, San Paolo – IMI / Cardine Banca; in both cases, a substantial contrast between 8 4 That outcome was probably favoured by the role the CB endeavoured in past times and the TUB, at art. 5, did not clarify the situation, by summing up both the guarantee of competition and stability as the objectives of financial supervision. Actually the enforceability of multiple and indefinite regulatory objectives is already contested in other regulatory systems15. The Italian system made no exception, especially due to the inclusion of potentially conflicting objectives, stability and competition. This provision, together with the absence of a separate antitrust scrutiny, may have strengthened the idea that BI is equipped with a pure discretionary power and in practice is free to strike a balance between conflicting objectives, at least in the exercise of the powers provided for by the TUB. The prevalence of the stability objectives and their impact on antitrust merger review may be also explained with reference to the specific features of the art. 19 TUB authorization power and the Handbook for regulated firms issued by BI. The authorization process for the acquisition of shares of banking firms used to have a prevailing role in the actual dynamics of the consolidation process for several reasons. First of all, from a substantive point of view, the assessment of sound and prudent management of the target bank involves the evaluation of the industrial plan of the acquirer. According to some scholars in this evaluation most of the discretion of BI is retained, since it can carry out a structural and preventive control on the external expansion of the firm and it can give guidance on the external and internal expansion path the bank is to follow16. Moreover, whenever the acquirer of shares is another bank, the operation will be assessed according to art. 53 TUB too, in order to evaluate the impact the operation will have on the acquirer balance sheet. Furthermore, from a procedural point of view, the art. 19 TUB power implies a different timing, compared to merger review. On one hand, the TUB provides BI with the power to authorize minority acquisition above 5% of capital, according to the several quotas set in the Handbook17; BI then may influence the dynamics at a very preliminary stage of the merger. On the other hand, the Handbook requires the firm willing to carry out a merger to send a preliminary notice18: this step is not provided for in the TUB, but it is only prescribed by the Handbook. Accordingly, this informal phase does not imply for BI a duty to act expressly; in fact the obligation to notice the BI the AGCM advise and the final decision can be found: the AGCM did not found the acquisitions substantially affecting the competitiveness of the market (see par. 13 AGCM Advise n. 11022, 25th of July 2002 and Advise n. 10732, 9th of May 2002), whereas BI authorized the operations with some behavioural conditions. BI Provv. n. 48, 9th of August 2003, Banca popolare commercio e industria/Banca popolare di Bergamo, where the AGCM in fact advised not to authorize the merger (AGCM Advise n. 12351, 7th of August 2003). 15 With reference to the FSMA 2000, where the regulatory objectives are narrowly defined and homogeneously grouped, the enforceability is highly contested, see E. LOMNICKA, Making the Financial Services Authority accountable, in Journal of business law, January 2000, 77. Contrary advise has been expressed by the Parliamentary Delegated Powers Committee, and the Joint Committee, see A. ADAMI, La regolazione dei mercati finanziari nel Regno Unito dopo il FSMA 2000, Torino, 2004, 30. 16 See G. OLIVIERI, Tutela del risparmio e concentrazioni bancarie: il ruolo dell’antitrust, in Banca Impresa Società, 2004, 444. 17 BI Handbook, Circolare n. 229, 21st of April 1999, Titolo II, Cap I, Sez. II, n. 1, an express authorization is due when the shareholder exceeds 5%, 10%, 15%, 20%, 33%, 50% of the capital, and in any case when the acquisition leads to achieve the control of the bank. 18 ,BI Handbook, Titolo II, Cap. I, Sez. II, n. 3. 5 arises at a very preliminary phase, before the operation has been assessed by the Executive Board, and nevertheless it requires the firm to supply very detailed information on the merger19. The likely inconsistency of this provision with the national and Community legal framework pushed the new BI Governor, Prof. Draghi, to withdraw such a provision, thus the Handbook has been modified on that point the 28th of August 2006. Furthermore, it may be stressed the different structure of the antitrust merger scrutiny, compared to the supervisory assessment on the shareholders. According to art. 16 of the Italian antitrust law, it is not provided a prior authorization model, rather a negative licensing scheme: after the notification of the operation, the antitrust authority is bound by a strict deadline (30 days) in order to issue the statement of objection. Once the deadline is expired, the authority does not hold any power to forbid the operation anymore, unless specific circumstances are verified. The scrutiny according to art. 19 TUB, on the contrary, is based on a prior authorization model, where the operation is cleared only after an express decision is issued by BI. Actually the prior authorization structure may be considered quite at odd with the Community provisions on access to banking market, as contained at art. 19 of directive 2006/48. The supervisory assessment on shareholders as shaped in the directive is clearly structured as a negative licensing system. Actually other important European financial regulatory systems have implemented this provision according to the wording and the spirit of the Directive. The FSMA 2000 provides, at art. 188, par. 3, that the Financial Services Authority, whenever decides to object the proposed operation, must issue the warning notice within 3 months from the firm’s notice20. According to art. 2b, par. 1a, of the German Banking Act (Kreditwesengesetz, KWG) the Federal Banking Supervisory Office may prohibit the acquisition of shares within three months from the receipt of the full application21 The Italian implementation made by the TUB as a positive licensing system may be highly contested, in terms of consistency with the Community system. The faculty to implement art. 19 of the Directive in a stricter way is provided for in the 12th recital, but it is doubtful whether the introduction of a positive licensing system may be deemed consistent with that faculty. Indeed the possibility to have stricter rules may be surely referred to the conditions to be fulfilled, provided that the ban of structural supervision contained in art. 7 is respected. However, with regard to the procedural system, the general limitations on of Community law on prior authorization systems may be recalled. According to the Guidelines of the Commission22 and the case law of the Court of Justice, the adoption of positive licensing systems, especially when they are not based on public, objective and stable criteria, may be not consistent with the 19 Actually the change of relevant aspects of the preliminary project will require a new notice, point 3.1. “If the Authority decides to give a warning notice under this section, it must do so before the end of the period of three months beginning: (a) in the case of a notice to be given under section 187(1), with the date on which it became aware of the failure to comply with the duty in question; (b) in the case of a notice to be given under section 187(3), with the date on which it became aware of the matters in question. ”. The wording of the article suggests that a warning notice issued after the expiring period may be considered an ultra vires act. 21 “Die Bundesanstalt kann innerhalb von drei Monaten nach Eingang der vollständigen Anzeige nach Absatz 1 den beabsichtigten Erwerb der bedeutenden Beteiligung oder ihre Erhöhung untersagen, wenn Tatsachen die Annahme rechtfertigen…“ 22 Communication of the Commission on certain legal aspects concerning intra-EU investment, in OJ, 19th of July 1997, C 220/15. 20 6 fundamental freedoms of the Treaty. Moreover, the Court has clearly stated that positive licensing systems affecting the fundamental freedoms may be admitted only in case that less restrictive mechanisms would not be able to achieve the public interest23. With regard to the prudential supervision on shareholders, this argument looses most of its strength, since the suitability of a negative licensing system is evidenced by the directive itself. Finally, in December 2005, the Italian system of supervision on acquisition of shares has been the object of an infraction procedure by the Commission. Moreover, a recent Commission proposal aims at modifying the wording of art. 19 of directive 2006/48, with the explicit objective of achieving a full harmonization of the supervisory control on shareholders24; the proposal recalls the negative licensing system contained in the actual art. 19, but it does not allow the adoption of stricter rules and, in addition, it specifies the sound and prudent requirements, by setting up five conditions to be fulfilled in order to forbid the operation. Finally, the concentration of competences, by internalizing both the assessment on stability and competitive effects of the operation, allowed BI to implement an active supervisory policy, i.e. an assessment of positive stability effects of the operation vis à vis the negative ones on competition. This “implied” power, which is not expressly mentioned in the TUB and the antitrust law, probably emerged from the concentration of competences. Thus the discretion the BI enjoyed in carrying out its function stemmed both from the several public interest objectives it was asked to look after and its supremacy (in procedural terms too) in the application of antitrust and stability rules. That led to a softened application of the failing firm defence25, a strict control on the aggregation of local banks and a general prejudice against hostile bids26. Both these attitudes are grounded on sole stability reasons, as minimizing the external costs of bank failures meanwhile limiting the too big to fail problem or limiting the stability concerns due to excessive price paid by the hostile bidder, without reference on the possible competitive impact.. In general terms the discretion the BI was left with may ease the perpetuation of an implicit planning role of CB, by means of its moral suasion. Moreover, the procedural framework characterizing the division of competences and the individual proceedings, the resulting lack of transparency, may have helped to minimize the substantive impact of the epochal change in financial sector regulation brought on by the substantive rule of Community directives and the internal application by means of the TUB. The idea underlying the present paper is that path dependency with regard to the style of banking supervision did not actually stemmed directly (or only) from the substantive provisions, but from the allocation of competences and, in some measure, the procedural structure the legal framework designed too. Despite the Community 23 Cfr Corte di Giustizia, sent. 14 dicembre 1994, Sanz de Lera, cause riunite C-163/94, C-165/94, C250/94, parr. 23-38; sent. 1° giugno 1999, Konle, causa C-302/97; sent. 20 febbraio 2001, Analir et al., causa C-205/99, par. 35. 24 Art. 5 of the Commission proposal on the harmonization of shareholders control 25 See BI provv. n. 1, 5th of April 1993, Banco di Sardegna/Banca popolare di Sassari. 26 V. MELI – LI IOCCHIO, Contendibilità del controllo delle banche: il ruolo della vigilanza, in Concorrenza e Mercato, 2000, 309, 327. 7 Directives on financial regulation do not explicitly impose a given regulatory structure and procedure, the provision of a conditional regulatory regime27 called for a change of the enforcing system too. In law 262/05 a first attempt to change the structure of supervisory architecture of financial regulation may be found: being politically unfeasible the institution of a single regulatory agency on financial markets, articles 1924 may be interpreted as a first step in order to sketch the fundamental elements for a network of financial regulators, with common procedural rules and based on a common informational base. Besides these basic elements, the law leaves the regulatory bodies involved with the task to build the network. In fact, beyond the homogenization of the administrative regime, the law does not go further towards the definition of the network, whereas the uncertainty in the allocation of competences between the AGCM and BI may represent a serious obstacle for the establishment of a cooperative setting. THE INTERRELATION GAME BETWEEN ANTITRUST AND STABILITY CONTROLS: THE SPECIFIC CASE OF MERGERS In recent times, boosted by bank scandals involving the Governor of BI and in the view of the evolution/consolidation of banking sector, the Italian legislator was forced to reconsider the allocation of competences between the AGCM and the Central Bank. Actually this has been a clear occasion to review the efficiency of the path dependent allocation of antitrust competences made in 1990. An interesting interpretation of the interrelations between AGCM and BI was put forward by Messori (2004)28, where a game theory approach in the explanation of possible strategic interactions between the two authorities is proposed with specific regard to the merger authorization procedure, the most problematic issue. The author points out as a cooperative outcome may not be feasible in the short period, when AGCM and BI will have to establish the relative reputation in defining the borders of their new competences. Moreover it is stressed that a simultaneous interrelation may worsen the non cooperative feature of the game and may lead to a joint refusal of authorizations, in order not to admit the veto power of the other authority. If built sequentially, the incentive not to act cooperatively is lessened, especially if backed by a clear definition of the objective of the administrative intervention and a transparent procedure, which may help to avoid strategic behaviour of the authorities. In particular, the author proposed a two stage game were AGCM is asked to decide on the antitrust compatibility of the operation and afterwards BI has to assess the stability effects of the mergers deemed to be compatible by AGCM. Messori’s proposal relies on the strong assumption that mergers may not be used as a stability instruments, thus anticompetitive mergers may not be authorized on the basis of their necessity for stability reasons29. In this setting the admissibility of the failing firm defence would be judged only by the AGCM, on the basis of the very strict requisites set by the European Commission in the Kali/Saltz decision. According to this view, BI is asked to exercise 27 L. TORCHIA, Il controllo pubblico della finanza privata, Padova, 1992. M. MESSORI, Un commento, in Mercato Concorrenza Regole, 2004, 401. 29 Ibidem, 403. 28 8 its authorization power only with regard to the negative effects on stability the operation may bring out. The interrelation game between the two authorities becomes even more complex in the likely case of conditioned authorizations. According to art. 6 par. 2 of the antitrust law, the antitrust authority may authorize a merger, meanwhile imposing conditions in order to cut off the possible anticompetitive concerns of the operation. Similarly, BI currently imposes prescriptions to be followed in implementing the operation, on the basis of its prudential supervisory powers (art. 53 TUB). In a simultaneous setting, the risk of a conflict between the conditions prescribed by one authority and the other’s is high, and actually they can change the evaluation itself of the operation carried on by the other authority30. A solution endeavoured during the legislative process: art. 26 of proposal 2436/05 In practice among the several proposals presented at the Italian Parliament, it may be worthy underlining art. 26 of the joined proposal n. 2436 presented at the Chamber of Deputies the18th of January 2005. In this proposal the allocation of antitrust competences between the AGCM and BI turned out to be finally based on a functional criterion, i.e. on the objectives of regulation31. The application of the prohibitions of art. 2 and 3 of law 287/90 (anticompetitive agreements and abuses) did not generally raise excessive problems: the system would have provided general competence for the AGCM with an advisory role of BI, symmetrically with the former regime. BI would have had the possibility to express its view only on the light of stability reasons, but without the possibility to forbid the operation, unless it implied a violation of other rules of TUB. Exemptions would have been accorded with a joint decision, but anyway on the ground of the conditions laid down in art. 4 par. 1 l. 287/90, with the need that benefits to consumers derive from stability reasons being assessed by BI. The merger review brought about more problems, since more clearly stability and competitive effects may derive simultaneously and the control on the structural dynamics of the market is at the stake. The proposal provided a parallel procedure, where the notification of the operation would have been addressed to both the authorities, but each one would have had scrutinized the application according to the regulatory objectives of its competences (stability concerns for BI, competitive ones for AGCM), coherently to an allocation scheme based on the function carried. According to the outcome of the scrutiny, the relationships between the AGCM and BI powers would have had different shape. In the case the concentration may negatively affect the 30 The risk of miscoordination is particularly high in one way, as the supervisory prescriptions (like sale of some assets in order to fit the capital ratios) may change the competitive effects of the operation and require different evaluations on the antitrust side. 31 See G. DI GIORGIO – ORGII NOIA, Financial market regulation and supervision: how many peaks for the Euro area, 28 Brooklyn journal of international law, 2002, 463. 9 stability of the system, the refusal to carry on the operation by BI was to be notified to AGCM, and that would have led to the impossibility to strike the deal, lacking one of the authorizations needed. In case the operation would be deemed necessary for the guarantee of the stability, BI was called to communicate its decision to AGCM, which in turn had to concede its authorization unless the competitive concerns of such an operation are not proportional to the stability gains. Finally if the stability effects had been irrelevant, the AGCM would have been free to adopt its decision only on competitive grounds. The dual system shaped by the proposal implied a dynamic setting of coordination between BI and AGCM: whenever the intervention of BI aims at protecting the stability in negative terms, the BI refusal absorbed the AGCM competence, since the operation may not be concluded, regardless the outcome of the competitive scrutiny. On the contrary, if the BI intervention aims at protecting the stability in positive terms, the AGCM was left with the ultimate power of balancing the stability gains vis a vis the competitive concerns. Corollary of this allocation of competences would have been the application of transparent procedural provisions aiming at guaranteeing due process of law, both in front of the AGCM and BI, with the application of AGCM procedural provisions contained in Reg. 217/98 meanwhile ad hoc regulation with a similar degree of transparency would have been adopted by BI. Despite the fact that for the first time the BI antitrust competences were at the stake, the art. 26 proposal probably did not manage to cut off the prominence of BI within the system. Actually the proposal relied on a formalization of BI-AGCM coordination directly by the law. In game theory terms the proposed art. 26 may be interpreted as a sequential game where BI acts as first mover, but its power to influence the decision of AGCM by selecting the possible choices of AGCM is limited. Actually the only inhibitory power BI had, involved cases where the stability may be negatively affected by the operation, whereas in the other cases (indifference or necessity for stability) the AGCM keeps the last word, even if in the latter case its discretion is limited to evaluate the proportionality of measures involved. The positive planning role of BI is reduced since its solitary power is retained only in negative terms and it may be grounded only on stability reasons. On the other side there could have been a perverse incentive for BI to expand its veto power by denying the authorization in order to limit AGCM power. In order to limit this incentive, the transparency of procedure carries out a crucial role, since the adversarial nature the relationship between BI and the undertakings in this case would make more likely and effective and stringent judicial review. In any case the proposed art. 26 was not approved by the Parliament Committee, and the problem of the allocation of competences has been solved in a different way in the recent law 262/05, s.c. “legge a tutela del risparmio”, or saving law The allocation of competences in law 262/05 Actually the solution of the problem adopted by the recent art. 19 para. 11-14 of the saving law disregarded the text and the philosophy itself inspiring the former art. 26 of the proposal 2346. On one hand it might have positive effects in reducing the Central Bank-centrism of the balance of competences, whereas on the other the new setting is already raising some conflicts of competences because of a lack of clarity in the scope 10 of new AGCM powers. Actually the wording of the article suggests an intensification of the regulatory burden, with an extension of the scrutinizing agencies even for non concentrative operations. More specifically, with regard to the application of art 2 and 3 of l. 287/90 (agreements and abuses), art. 19 par. 11 provides full competence of AGCM, without any advisory role of BI, whereas for the exemption ex art. 4 par. 1 it has been maintained the joint competence of BI and AGCM provided for in art. 20 par. 5, law 287/90. In fact the most serious problems are due to the allocation of competences for merger review. Rather than simplifying the relative competences of the two authorities and reducing the burden of regulation of the consolidation process in banking sector, the new setting may lead to an extension of ex ante regulatory powers of both BI and AGCM. The major problem lies in the fact that the AGCM ex ante scrutiny would be extended to all the cases covered by art. 19 TUB, which involves the need of authorization for the acquisitions of shares of banks above 5%. Actually the scope of application of art. 19 is only partially coincident with the scope of application of the classical merger review, since it can involve non concentrative operations. Obviously the assessments of BI and AGCM will be carried out with regard to different public interests objectives and motivations, being the safeguard of stability for the former and the guarantee of competition for the latter. However the law prescribes that the two assessments have to be attached in a joint decision issued by both the authorities within 60 days from the application. It is not clear from the text of the article whether the art. 19 gives the ground for a new competence of AGCM which is different (at least from a procedural point of view) from the merger review or it just implies that applications according to art. 19 TUB may be substantially scrutinized by AGCM only in case the acquisition turns out to be a merger32. Actually the wording of the article would suggest a new competence at least with regard to the procedural grounds, first of all because the new terms introduced by art. 19 par. 13 (60 days) are incompatible with the normal merger review procedure (the two steps procedure lasts up to 75 days, 30 days for phase I and 45 for phase II). On the other side the grounds upon which the AGCM may be called to express its antitrust evaluation of the non concentrative operations is less clear. There may be vertical effects of participations in banks, mainly affecting the principle of separation of banks from industry, and this rule may reintroduce a competitive assessment of these relationships as provided once in art. 27 and ff. of the original version of law 287/90. Moreover there could be horizontal effects of cross-participations. However these effects may be scrutinized by AGCM according its normal antitrust competences in applying art. 2 and 3 of law 287/9033, so it is doubtful whether a specific ex ante authorization procedure is really necessary. 32 See M. CLARICH – RICH ARAMILLI, Regolazione a tutela della stabilità e concorrenza¸ text of the intervention at Paradigma Workshop on the new law 262/05, Milan, 1st of March. 33 For a review of the possible anticompetitive effects of minority acquisition of shares and the juridical framework at the EC level, see R. A. STRUIJLAART, Minority share acquisitions below the control threshold of the EC Merger control Regulation: An economic and legal analysis, in 25 World Competition, 2002, 173 and ff. 11 On the other side the new setting of competences contained in art. 19 l. 262/05 may have effects of the extension of BI powers too. Actually the joint competence of BI and AGCM could be interpreted as involving the faculty of BI to scrutinize operations being a merger according to art. 5 l. 287/90 but that do not involve the acquisition of shares by the participants and thus that would not need the authorization by BI according to the competence set out by art. 19 or 57 TUB. Some of these aspects have been afforded by the two authorities, looking for coordination in the definition of their respective competences (see infra) Furthermore, procedural problems may be given by the relationships between the BI Handbook, regulating the art. 19 TUB authorization procedure in front of BI, and their effects on the AGCM competence, even on the basis of their ambivalent juridical nature34: for instance it is doubtful the need for a preliminary notice to AGCM. Similarly, if the AGCM review is based on a new competence linked to art. 19 TUB, the firm will be asked to attach the industrial plan of the acquisition to the AGCM notice too. On the other side, if the AGCM is not to act according to art. 19 TUB, but just on the basis of its general merger review competence, that would imply the application of the antitrust law provisions on procedure, which highly differ from the actual secreted procedure characterizing the BI competence (f.i. with regard to the participation of third parties). In the law 262/05 no words are spent for the definition of competences in case of necessary mergers for the safeguard of stability of the system, unlike the proposed art. 26. As a consequence it could be sustained that BI does not have anymore any active role in defining in positive terms the need of some market operations in order to secure stability objectives. According to art. 19 par. 13 each authority has to provide a motivation to its decision with regard to its competences, thus BI may not bind AGCM to authorize a merger for its positive effects on stability if it has a negative impact on competition. Actually AGCM does not have this exemption power in mergers35, without a Ministerial Decree according to art. 25 law 287/90, and according to the European Commission the failing firm defence may be applied only under strict conditions36. Finally it will be interesting to evaluate the effects of the new setting of competences with regard to merger remedies the two authorities may impose on the firms involved in order to authorize operations which raise problematic issues. As recently confirmed by the Lazio Regional Administrative Court, BI is enabled to impose conditions (melius prescriptions) on the firm seeking to acquire bank shares, in order to 34 On the several problems on the normative or administrative nature of the BI Instructions, see M. CLARICH, Per uno studio sui poteri normativi della Banca d’Italia, in Banca Impresa Società, 2003, 65; M. A. STEFANELLI, Le istruzioni di vigilanza della Banca d’Italia – Parte generale, Padova, 2003 35 Unlike art. 21 of Reg. 139/04. 36 Being a) the target firm would have been inevitably forced out of the market, b)the acquiring firm would inevitably acuire the market share, being the only relevant competitor, c) no less anti-competitive purchase was admitted, see Case IV/M308, Kali und Salz/MdK/Treuhand in Common Market Law Review, 1994, 526 and ECJ, case C-68/94 and 30/95, France v. Commision, SCPA v. Commission, 1998, ECR I-1375. 12 maintain the “safe and sound” management of the target bank and of the acquirer37. Actually these measures may have both structural and behavioural aspects. Since the remedies imposed may overturn the initial features of the operation, it would be necessary to coordinate the conditions imposed by both the authorities within the joint decision that has to be issued within 60 days from the application. The provision of a joint statement including the decisions of two independent authorities is a novelty for the Italian juridical system. Unlike the usual scheme of compounded decisions, art. 19 par. 13 suggests that actually two different final decisions are taken, whereas the overall authorizative effect will derive only from the consistency of the provisions. In this way the system aims at imposing a forced informal coordination between the two authorities,. The degree of such a coordination, however, highly depends from the interpretation given to the joint act: on one side a formalistic interpretation may lead to a mere joint publication of two different administrative acts; on the other side, a substantial interpretation may provide an enforceable mechanism of coordination, due to the fact that inconsistency of the two final decisions may be challenged in the Court (see infra)38. Actually the first case handled by the two authorities showed a very formalistic approach: the two proceedings (in front of the AGCM and BI) have been carried on separately, and the joint act resulted in a simple joint publication of two different decisions39. Compared with the former setting, the externalization of antitrust scrutiny will surely require a clear definition of the relationship between the juridical grounds of the powers of the two authorities. However it may have a further effect: the new setting of competences sharpens the problem of a clear definition of the boundaries between the two objectives of regulation within the TUB, the competitiveness and the stability, as provided at art. 5 TUB. Actually the new setting may imply a deep change of the “regulatory regime”40, with a shift from the former “monitoring monopoly power”41 towards a strengthened role of market incentives, especially with regard to corporate control, secured by the antitrust scrutiny. In other words, by externalizing the different functions, the clash of objectives will be made public, thus observable, since it will cause an institutional conflict. The main problem, thus, relies on the procedural means to solve such a conflict. From a comparative point of view, the 2000 Financial Services and Markets Act in UK faces this problem in an interesting way. Notwithstanding the English experience is characterized by the single regulator model, the FSA is not appointed for the application of antitrust rules. But the relationship between competitiveness and stability 37 See TAR Lazio, sez. I, 19th of July 2005, n. 6157, in Giornale di diritto amministrativo, 2006, 309, with a comment by A. TRAVI and in Foro amministrativo – TAR, 2005, 3564, with a comment by E. L. CAMILLI. 38 About the two possible interpretations of the joint act see E. GUERRI, Le modifiche alle competenze in materia antitrust introdotte con la legge di riforma della tutela del risparmio e la disciplina dei mercati finanziari, in Il diritto dell’economia, 2006, 285-286. 39 Provv. C7669 del 5 luglio 2006 - Société Générale Italia Holding/2s Banca, in Bollettino AGCM, n. 27 del 24 luglio 2006, 5-12. 40 For the concept of regulatory regime in financial markets see D. LLEWELLYN, A regulatory regime for financial stability, ONB Working paper, n. 48, 2001. 41 D. LLEWELLYN, op. cit. supra, 20. 13 of the financial system is not only addressed in negative terms. In a highly regulated market, the implementation of a competitive market is highly based on the minimization of the anticompetitive impact of sector rules. Indeed, in an attempt to increase as much as possible the accountability of the financial regulator42 the FSMA does not mention the need to maintain the competitiveness of the financial system as a positive objective to be pursued by the sector specific authority, rather it represents a negative boundary of the FSA regulatory powers (see Sec. 2 par. 3 FSMA 2000)43. The idea of a practical conflict between the financial objectives and the competitiveness suggested a clear definition of competences the sector regulation is aimed at. Within these objectives, the FSA is left with ample discretion in implementing its regulatory powers, but it is obliged to minimize the impact of its measures on the competitive process. The fulfilment of this requirement, however, is not left to the judicial review, that probably might sanction only macroscopic infringement of the proportionality principles involving a discharge of the positive objectives. Actually, the antitrust agency, the OFT, is given the power to review this latter aspect, by means of public reports to the Competition Commission and the Treasury. The discretion of the FSA is then limited by means of a possible scrutiny of the antitrust agency, in the extent the FSA regulation may distort competition. That implies that regulation is entitled to derogate the normal market discipline as far as its action is proportional to the aim, and the respect of this boundary is given to the competitive review by OFT and eventually solved at political level by the government. (Part. X, Chapter III, “Competition scrutiny”, sec. 159-164). Whenever the two set of regulations are in conflict with regard to single cases, however, the FSMA provides for an exclusion of application of the 1998 Competition Act, being in general not applicable the cartel and the abuse of dominant position prohibition for action carried out according to FSA rules and guidance (Sec. 164 FSMA 2000). The UK, then, adopted a system, where a possible conflict between objectives will not be dealt with regard to the specific case, but it will lead to a more general scrutiny of the regulatory system set up by the FSA. In terms of reputation, this competition scrutiny may be even more harmful than the contrast within a single case, then it incentives the FSA to minimize the anticompetitive impact of its regulation. Moreover, that system makes the conflict public and it shifts the decision on the conflict at a political level, since the balance between public objectives is at stake44. At domestic level, given that the saving law does not provide any substantive and procedural solution of a possible conflict between the antitrust agency and the supervisory authority, first of all it may be useful verify what are the boundaries (in 42 See E. HÜPKES – PKESUINTYN – INTYN LAYLOR, The accountability of financial sector supervisors: Principles and practice, IMF Working Paper n. 05/51, 2005, 11 and ff., where it is underlined the importance of the definition of clear and not conflicting objectives. 43 The FSMA clearly distinguish between “regulatory objectives” and “relevant considerations”. While the former entail sector specific targets of financial regulation aimed at stability protection (market confidence, public awareness, protection of consumers, reduction of financial crime), the latter have a broader value and surely lack of binding power, see A. ADAMI, op. cit., 2004, 41. 44 A partially different competitive scrutiny of the sector specific regulator can also be found in the American system. The adversarial nature of the conflict in this case is however more evident: the application of antitrust rules is demanded to the several sector specific regulator, but the Department of Justice may challenge the decision in front of the court (the s.c. revolving door). In this case the institutional conflict will be dealt at the judiciary level, rather that at the political one, as it happened in the famous Philadelphia case. 14 substantive and procedural terms) each authority has to respect in order to reach a deal within the single case. On one side, as already said, the 1993 Banking law includes the achievement of a competitive banking system among the general objectives of the supervisory authority (art. 5). That implies the need to choose, among the different tools available in order to achieve the stability objective, the ones that better match the competitive process45. Despite the different wording with respect to the FSMA, where it is stated in negative terms, it may be supported the idea that the article implies the need to minimize the anticompetitive impact of its power (being rule-making or adjudicatory powers). A different vision, that would require an interventionist approach of the supervisory authority, may be at odd both with the shift of competences happened with the saving law on antitrust matters and with the need to preserve the undertaking’s business autonomy. On the other side the 1990 antitrust law does not provide the same degree of flexibility with regard to the balance between different public interest objectives: the possibility to disregard the anticompetitive impact of some measures is provided for by the antitrust law at art. 4 and 20 par. 5 (exemption for anticompetitive agreement) under strict conditions, whereas with regard to merger scrutiny the AGCM does not have any autonomous exemption power. As long as the Government will not exercise the power provided for at art. 25 (see supra), the AGCM is not entitled to grant exemptions for anticompetitive mergers. Furthermore, it is very unlikely that the actual banking market structure may impose serious competitive concerns that can lead to a prohibition of the operation46. It is more likely that an operation will be cleared, under specific conditions. However, the AGCM power to impose conditions on mergers is subjected to a strict judicial review, according to the recent developments of the Supreme Administrative Court on that point47. Together with the open procedure applicable in merger review, that shows a remarkable difference on the accountability degree of the two authorities’ decision-making process. In game theory terms the new setting seems to refer to a simultaneous game, where neither the AGCM nor the BI competences are well ex ante defined. The non cooperative outcome may lead to increased difficulty to obtain an authorization or the imposition of coherent remedies, especially at the initial stage of application of the law. Actually at the beginning of the interaction game, the pay offs of the Authorities involved in terms of relative reputation will be even higher in case of non collaboration 45 C. LAMANDA, Le finalità della vigilanza, in F. FERRO LUZZI – ZASTALDI (a cura di), Commentario al testo unico bancario, Padova, 1996, 174. 46 During the 1990-2005 period, the AGCM advised not to authorize the merger in only two cases, Banco di Sardegna/Banca popolare di Sassari in 1993 and Banca popolare commercio e industria/Banca popolare di Bergamo in 2003. 47 See Consiglio di Stato, Sez. VI, 1st of October 2002, n. 5156, in Foro Italiano, 2003, 3. The review by the Supreme Administrative Court on the remedies imposed by the AGCM in the merger Enel-Infostrada has been quite strict. As a consequence of the conglomeral merger between Enel and Wind, the AGCM found that the dominant position of Enel in the electricity distribution market may be strengthened, since it would be the sole multiutility firm operating both telecommunication and electricity services. In order to mitigate the anticompetitive impact, the AGCM required Enel to sell some generation capacity. With regard to remedies, the Court focused on two major points: first of all, on the causality link between the dominated market and the market where remedies were imposed, secondly on the proportionality of measures imposed, vis à vis the anticompetitive advantage stemming from the merger (par. 25). On the proportionality principle. 15 if the competences are not clearly defined, since it is necessary to establish a precedent. Each authority could look for an extensive interpretation of its competences and a reduction of other’s scope of powers. The recent Government proposal, issued the 31st of August and still under parliamentary review, aims at solving some inconsistencies of the saving law, as showed supra. First of all, the link between the art. 19 TUB power and the antitrust scrutiny is severed, in order to make clear that the AGCM merger review is carried out only on the ground of the antitrust law. As a consequence, the scope of application of AGCM power will be defined by art. 5 of the antitrust law, whereas BI will be left with the supervisory controls contained in art. 19 and 57 TUB. Secondly, the joint act is deleted, but at the same time the adoption of a unique deadline (60 days) for the two proceedings is maintained. In other words the simultaneous feature of the interrelation game is maintained. This will not be the case whenever a balance between stability and competitive reasons are at the stake. Grounded on stability reasons involving one or more of the banks involved in the operation, BI may ask the AGCM to authorize an operation that would strengthen a dominant position. In this case the last word on the compatibility of the operation is given to AGCM, which has to assess the proportionality of the competitive restraints vis à vis the stability objectives. THE COORDINATION WITHIN THE NETWORK With reference to the second aspect of the building process of the network, the saving law just sketches the possible instruments of collaboration among the authorities dealing with financial markets, as set up in art. 20 of the law. Actually the headless collaboration recalled in art. 20 may be of little utility: the article does not seem to have an innovative nature, since the instruments were already available according to normal administrative law (see art. 15 law 241/90, which was already used to arrange the AGCM-BI relationship within the old setting) and there is no explicit sanction for the infringement of cooperation obligation. Notwithstanding that, some rumours suggest that an agreement between the two antitrust authorities and the Central Bank with regard to the scope of competences on merger scrutiny has been achieved. According to this “agreement” the AGCM won’t open an investigative phase if the transfer of shares does not involve a merger, according to art. 5 of the antitrust law. However, the solution of the substantive problems related to the coordination of the public interests on competition and stability have not been addressed by the two authorities. If a cooperative attitude between the two authorities will come up with regard to merger scrutiny, i.e. if the pay offs of both authorities arising from the choice to collaborate will be anyway higher than the pay offs resulting from a non cooperative outcome, it is left to the two bodies to strike a balance, in order to cooperatively carry out this new “mixed” competence. For instance, it will be necessary the adoption of coherent remedies for stability and antitrust purposes. The remarked differences on the accountability of the decision-making processes of the two authorities may help to sketch a possible coordination path. Indeed, the higher degree of accountability provided for in the antitrust law acts as a commitment in the institutional bargaining process between BI and AGCM. Such a process may finally result in the measures 16 eventually required for stability reasons being de facto subjected to a competition scrutiny. Furthermore, pure anticompetitive mergers grounded only on stability reasons could not be cleared by the antitrust authority, which is bound by the restrictive interpretation of the failing firm doctrine adopted by the Commission. On the other side, BI is obliged to minimize the anticompetitive impact of the measures imposed, then it may be forced to adapt as much as possible the proposed remedies, within the available set of conditions compatible with the stability objective. The informational network art. 21 of the saving law tries to sketch will have a particular relevance for the achievement of a cooperative setting, even if the different degree of protection of information within the network may raise problematic issues. With specific regard to the impact on the division of competences between antitrust and banking authorities, it has to be positively noticed that the AGCM, unlike past art. 7 TUB, is now included within the financial regulators network, thus it has access to the information held not only by the banking regulator, but to CONSOB, ISVAP and COVIP databases too. Besides these attempts to strengthen the coordination among the authorities involved, the law 262/05 tries to build up a certain degree of uniformity with regard to the institutional and procedural setting. Articles 23 and 24 provides a common juridical framework for the exercise of financial supervision powers, either involving Bank of Italy and the others authorities of the network (except the AGCM). The harmonization of the administrative regime required major changes for BI, which already issued a new regulation48 consistent with the new regime. A major change, f.i., has been the generalization of the obligation to issue a statement of objections before the final decision: such an obligation was indeed excluded for certain proceedings carried out by BI. Within this harmonized framework, however, a notable exception has been anyway maintained: the role of the CICR has not been changed. Actually the CICR is still at the top of the institutional setting of stability supervision in Italy. The nature of this Committee is still under debate: on one side the law appoints the Committee with some specific tasks (mainly of regulatory nature), on the other side there is a strong relevance of political bodies within it (the major ministries dealing with economic affairs), together with the mandatory presence of BI. Actually a similar body is not provided for in other institutional settings involving the other independent authorities dealing with financial matters. Actually the architecture of financial regulatory network would require either a common high level political Committee, involved in the overall financial regulation and implementing the coordination of the entire network, or a complete independence of each single peak regulator from the government, together with a credible coordinating mechanism. The actual framework, on the opposite, suggests a different role of political power in the stability supervision compared with other peaks of regulation. That would means, for instance, that regulatory changes 48 Regolamento 27 giugno 2006, “Regolamento recante l’individuazione dei termini e delle unità organizzative responsabili dei procedimenti amministrativi di competenza della Banca d’Italia relativi all’esercizio delle funzioni di vigilanza in materia bancaria e finanziaria, ai sensi degli articoli 2 e 4 della legge 7 agosto 1990, n. 241, e successive modificazioni”, in G.U. n. 159 dell’11 luglio 2006, Supp. Ord. n. 162. 17 involving both BI and Consob regimes would require a different involvement of political forces and that may represent a serious obstacle towards the coordination of the authorities involved. The new governmental proposal may be even more inconsistent with the harmonization of the system: the CICR is held at the top of the stability institutional framework, but the Presidency (which is given to the Ministry of Economic Affairs by the law) retains the power to ask the other major authorities involved in the regulation to attend the Committee, without any voting power. Actually the change would not modify the asymmetrical architecture of stability regulation, whereas at the same time it can strengthen the political component of the CICR: the Treasury indeed may strategically use its power, by inviting the other authorities in order to strengthen its positions within the Committee. Without a change of the CICR competences (extended on the whole financial regulation, thus not involving the sole stability side) and of its mandatory composition, the ambivalent role of this body is not wiped away and the road map to a real coordination among the different regulatory peaks will not be completed. A possible alternative, which would reinforce the independence of regulatory bodies, would require the elimination of such a body, in order to cut off the possible influence of political power in financial regulation. CONCLUSIONS The allocation of competences provided for in law 262/05 suggests the way towards a functional approach has been opened and it may represent an evolution of the sector specific approach which characterized the financial sector up to now. The evolution towards a function-based regulatory network for financial services rather towards a single regulator may be considered an effect of past setting. Even after the legislative breakthrough of the 1993 Banking Law, the setting of competences based on a sector specific approach allowed BI to keep its leader role in banking regulation. The fact that one of the authority involved is the Central Bank and it used to have a strong planning role in banking, together with the different procedural constraints strengthened the BI asymmetrical role within the financial regulators and its leadership. On the other side the monetary function is not anymore an autonomous task of BI, then the effect on the structure of the financial network due to this competence of BI is lessened. However, being the role of banks still prevalent in the Italian financial landscape, the single regulator was probably likely to be BI. Being this outcome politically unfeasible, the reform adopted an imperfect functionalist approach. Imperfect because some relevant growing sectors (investment funds and insurance) are still under the supervision of sector specific authorities (COVIP and ISVAP), even if the law aims at building a financial regulatory network between these bodies. Furthermore, the transparency of banking activities is still supervised by the BI together with CONSOB. With regard to supervisory and antitrust competences, however, the law pursued a complete shift towards a pure functionalist approach. The advantages stemming from this setting may be found in the possibility to limit the discretion of the authorities involved. Within some extent some flexibility of rules is needed to adapt general rules to specific cases, as the jurisprudence on the open 18 juridical clauses may show49. However such degree of discretion involves the practical implementation of the technical aspects needed to pursue the target the authority is appointed for (s.c. discrezionalità tecnica), but does not allow to weight off different public interests (s.c discrezionalità amministrativa). The appointment of different public bodies for the achievement of different public interests makes the conflict public. However, the lack of clarity in defining the relative competences may wipe out the advantages of the functionalist approach, raising serious coordinative problems50. Secondly the system has to provide the tools to cope with this institutional conflict. That may be addressed by formal means of coordination provided by the law or by informal “cheap talks” within the authorities involved, as it happened with regard to the definition of the scope of application of antitrust powers in merger review. Actually the coordination game between independent authorities of the network is affected both by the relative legislative definition of competences, the bundle of parallel competences each authority has and the different procedural rules of their administrative activity. If these aspects are not homogenously regulated and balanced, there may be the concrete risk that an authority will come up as natural leader of the network and it will be able to enforce a certain degree of discretion. Some provisions of the new saving law may have positive effects in the building process of a financial regulatory network, in order to substitute the strong interrelation between supervisory and monetary powers once characterized the BI leader role on supervision of financial markets. Both the new institutional framework of BI arranged by art. 19 and the homogenization of procedural rules for normative and individual administrative acts of financial regulatory bodies contained in art. 23-24 tend to limit the asymmetrical position BI once enjoyed within the network, especially from a procedural point of view51. It may be sustained that within the overall functions of the Central Bank, a strong differentiation from an administrative point of view between the regimes of monetary and supervisory competences is emerging52 and it endeavours an important element in order to limit the natural leader role BI is pushed to carry out within the financial regulatory network. This aspect represents the major breakthrough with the past setting and may help to shift from the path dependence in the enforcement of substantive antitrust rules. The creation of a regulatory network with a homogenous administrative regime and a regulation of the information stream within the network may represent the bulk for a coherent financial regulation, or at least a substitute of the single financial regulator, which on the contrary emerged in other countries. The Administrative Courts (especially the one of Lazio district and the Supreme Administrative Court, which will be competent for the judicial review of all the individual acts of the authorities included within the network, according to art. 24 of the saving law) recently anticipated this homogenization of the administrative regime of BI 49 See Consiglio di Stato, VI, 2199/02, 5156/02, 926/04. That may be indentified as redundancy, lacunae, inconsistency, that coordination aims to minimize, see B. G. PETERS, Managing horizontal government: the politics of co-ordination, in Public administration, 1998, 296. 51 See G. MONTEDORO, Procedimento e processo nella riforma sul risparmio, Report of the intervention at the Bar Congress held in Rome, 30th of March 2006, available at www.giustizia-amministrativa.it. 52 E.L. CAMILLI, Commento agli art. 19-22 della legge 262/05¸available at www.archivioceradi.it . 50 19 vis à vis the other independent administrative authorities. First of all they applied the special procedural rules provided for at art. 21bis law 1034/71 in challenging the administrative acts of independent administrative authorities53. In addition it was applied to BI acts the judicial review doctrine for the decision of independent administrative authorities54. It is then foreseeable that the path towards homogenization will not be hindered by the Courts. Furthermore, the comprehensive effect of the reform may sketch a new role for the AGCM within the network. Indeed, among the authorities of the network, the antitrust authority is the sole that does not endeavour any rule-making power and has a general competence (i.e. not limited to financial markets), which in some extent makes it at a weaker position, vis à vis the sector regulators. On the other side, as seen with specific regard of merger remedies, the AGCM is bound by its legislative statute to a single public interest, the safeguard of the competitive process, which more or less explicitly is addressed by the sector (or objective) specific regulations too55. The fulfilment in positive terms of the competition target by the sector regulatory agencies, however, may be problematic, since the sector specific regulator has a tendency to look after its objectives, whereas at the same time assessing the competitive effects of the sector regulations may be difficult, due to the limits of the judicial review, especially for general normative acts. Eventually the AGCM may act as a “watchdog” on the competitive impact of sector (or objective) regulations and decisions. Its advises in the consultation process of art. 23 of the saving law will have a special relevance, due to the fact that the antitrust advocacy function is eventually backed by the power to disregard non justified anticompetitive regulations, according to the CIF judgment56. On the other side some shortcomings of the law may hinder the correct functioning of the network. Notwithstanding the clear separation of competences operated by the law (BI does not either have an advisory power for the application of art. 2 and 3 of law 287/90), some overlaps remain with regard to the application of their respective set of rules on mergers. Firstly, it can be noticed that the “implied” power of BI to authorize anticompetitive mergers, on the basis of their positive effects on stability, probably vanished. The effects of this provision on the overall style of stability supervision may be significant, since they help to shift the core of supervisory activity from the structural control to the prudential supervision. There will be still some problems at stake, as the definition of a common procedure for the firm willing to apply for art. 19 TUB authorization. Actually the wording of the law is ambiguous: it would extend the antitrust preventive scrutiny far beyond its scope on non financial sectors and that may be a matter of conflict between the two authorities, both with regard to the procedure to be followed and the relative value of their powers. Despite the economic thought pointed out the consistency of stability objective with antitrust policy, the allocation of 53 Consiglio di Stato, Sez. VI, 5 settembre 2005 n. 4521, par. 2. TAR Lazio, Sez. VI, 19 luglio 2005, n. 6157. 55 See art. 5 TUB, art. 5 D. Lgs 58/1998 (Securities act), art. 3 D. Lgs. 209/2005 (Insurance code), 56 Consorizio Industriale Fiammiferi v. AGCM, dec. 9th of September 2003, case 198/01. 54 20 regulatory competences for antitrust and stability purposes is a problematic issue that may increase the competition among the two pillars of the network, BI and AGCM. This competition might be beneficial, if the law arranged a dispute settling mechanism, as other systems do. Otherwise, the joint authorization for non concentrative operations may increase the regulatory burden, i.e. barriers to entry, for investors in banking sector. The extent of this burden will depend on the degree of coordination and cooperative attitude the two institutions, AGCM and BI, will agree on. Within the actual legislative framework it is proposed a possible evolutionary path of the relationships between the two authorities, which adheres to the “watchdog” function of AGCM. With regard to the possible obstacles this evolutionary path may encounter, it may be useful a glance on the incentives to coordinate of the two authorities. A possible indirect instrument to enforce iterative coordination between the two authorities may be represented by the role of judicial review of the joint authorization decision. The assessment of the lawful use of power in the joint decision may follow two different methods. By separately assessing the two parts of the final decision, the judge may limit its role to the review of each single assessment, with the usual scope to verify the consistency of the single reasoning of each authority. Differently if the judicial review will be appointed on the overall consistency of the decision; in this case the proportionality principle, which nowadays is named as one of the guide principle of administrative activity57, will allow to a deeper scrutiny on the outcome of the coordination between the two authorities, especially with regard to the conditional measures imposed58. The risk that inconsistency of the decision may result to the annulment may provide BI and AGCM the incentive to coordinate within the authorization process. Within this system, the lack of clarity of the rules will shift to the judiciary the burden of practically defining the relationships within the network. This is an improper task the judiciary may be asked to carry out, that would imply high transaction costs for the market and would show a pathology of the system. Actually the resolution of the conflict between public interest objectives should be left to the Government, which is liable both in front of the electoral body and of the Community institutions. 57 Art. 1 par. 1, law 241/90 on the administrative procedural rules. Art. 23 law 262/05 on the proportionality of regulatory measures. 58 On the proportionality assessment of merger remedies, see supra, Enel/Infostrada case. 21