Bank competition and stability: Reconciling con‡icting empirical evidence Thorsten Becky Olivier De Jonghez Glenn Schepensx 22 May 2011 Abstract Theoretical models and empirical results o¤er con‡icting evidence on the relationship between bank competition and bank stability. This paper aims to reconcile the seemingly contrasting evidence on the bank competition-bank soundness relationship. We develop a uni…ed framework to assess how regulation, supervision and other institutional factors may make it more likely that the data favor one theory over the other (charter value paradigm versus risk-shifting paradigm). Cross-country heterogeneity in these factors allows us to test the assumptions and predictions of various theoretical models. We show that an increase in competition will have a larger impact on banks’ risk taking incentives in countries with stricter activity restrictions, more herding in revenue structure, unconcentrated banking markets and more generous deposit insurance. The authors would like to thank Fabio Castiglionesi, Hans Degryse, Claudia Girardone, Klaus Schaeck and seminar participants at HEC Paris, Ghent University, Tilburg University, Cass Business School, Roma II Tor Vergata, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Bangor Business School for interesting discussions and helpful comments. y CentER, European Banking Center, Tilburg University and CEPR. z CentER, European Banking Center, Tilburg University. x Corresponding author: [email protected]. Department of Financial Economics, Ghent University. 1 1 Introduction The impact of bank competition on …nancial stability remains a widely debated and controversial issue, both among policymakers and academics. The belief that …ercer competition among banks would lead to a more e¤ective banking system initiated a deregulating spiral in the late 70s and early 80s. While the deregulation of branching and activity restrictions may have resulted in more intense competition among banks, with positive repercussions, it may as well have had the unintended consequence of increasing banking sector instability.1 Similarly, the international process of banking liberalization seemingly has gone hand in hand with an increased occurrence of systemic banking crises in the last two decades of the twentieth century, culminating in the global …nancial crisis of 2007-2009. However, there is no academic consensus on whether bank competition leads to more or less stability in the banking system. On the one hand, an increase in loan market competition leads to lower lending rates and hence lower interest margins. As banks’ franchise values erode, this may create incentives to gamble and may lead to a shift towards riskier activities, because of the limited liability by bank shareholders that e¤ectively turns bank equity into a put option on banks ’pro…ts. On the other hand, a similar argument but in the opposite direction can be made for the bank’s borrowers. If entrepreneurs are confronted with lower loan rates, they will choose safer projects and have fewer incentives for aggressive risk taking, i.e. the adverse selection and moral hazard problems will be mitigated. These two opposite e¤ects may help in explaining why empirical studies across di¤erent samples and time periods fail to …nd a consensus on which e¤ect dominates. Moreover, comparing the results of di¤erent studies is complicated by the use of di¤erent competition and risk measures. A similar inconclusive debate as on the relationship between competition and stability has been led on the e¤ect of the regulatory framework on banks ’risk-taking incentives and ultimately bank stability. On the one hand, capital regulation and interest rate and activity restrictions 1 See among other Keeley (1990) and Jayaratne and Strahan (1998) 2 are seen as fostering stability (Hellmann, Murdock, and Stiglitz (2000)); on the other hand, they might lead to rent-seeking and might prevent banks from reaping necessary diversi…cation and scale bene…ts. The role of deposit insurance schemes has been especially controversial. While often introduced to protect small depositors’ lifetime savings and to prevent bank runs, they also provide perverse incentives to banks to take aggressive and excessive risks. These perverse incentives are held less in check in weak supervisory frameworks (Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (2002)). This paper combines the two literatures and assesses whether the relationship between competition and stability varies across markets with di¤erent regulatory frameworks, market structures and levels of institutional development. Speci…cally, while holding the measure of bank competition and stability constant across samples, we document that support for either the competitionstability or competition-fragility view varies across countries and over time. Next, we identify and test the possible channels that may create cross-country variation in the competition-stability relationship. While we identify several country characteristics that explain the cross-country variation in the competition-stability relationship, a large amount is still unexplained. Finally, based on our results, we try to reconcile the seemingly con‡icting existing empirical results on the competition-stability relationship. <Insert Figure 1 around here> As way of motivation, consider the cross-country variation in the relationship between competition and stability. In our sample of banks in 62 countries, the pairwise correlation2 between the Lerner index and the Z-score, widely used proxies for market power and bank soundness, respectively, is 0:25.3 Figure 1, however, reveals that this full sample correlation masks a substantial 2 We refer to simple pairwise correlation coe¢ cients in the introduction. A similar story can be made with regression based conditional relationships. However, for ease of exposition, we postpone this to later sections. 3 The Lerner index is the ratio of the di¤erene between price and marginal cost and the price, with higher values indicating higher market power. The Z-score is an accounting measure of bank distress. It is measured 3 degree of country-level heterogeneity. Each bar in Figure 1 corresponds to the country-speci…c pairwise correlation between market power and bank soundness. The average pairwise correlation over the 62 countries resembles the full sample correlation. However, there is a large amount of heterogeneity in the competition-stability relationship, with correlations ranging from below -0.2 to above 0.5. In some countries, the correlation is negative and signi…cant. In many others it is not statistically di¤erent from zero. In most countries, the number is positive and signi…cant. Rather than being interested in the sign of the relationship, we are interested in the cross-sectional dispersion. Speci…cally, we are interested in which country-speci…c features make it more likely that competition is less harmful or more bene…cial for bank soundness. Exploring the variation in the competition-stability relationship is important for academics and policy makers alike. The academic debate on the e¤ect of competition on bank stability has been inconclusive and by exploring factors that can explain variation in the relationship, this paper contributes to the resolution of the puzzle. Policy makers have been concerned about the e¤ect of deregulation and the consequent competition on bank stability but have also discussed di¤erent elements of the regulatory framework that have both an impact on competition and directly on stability, including deposit insurance capital regulation and activity restrictions. This paper shows a critical role for the regulatory framework in explaining the variation across countries and over time in the relationship between competition and stability and has therefore important policy repercussions. Our paper builds on a rich theoretical and empirical literature exploring the relationship between competition and stability in the banking system. On the one hand, the competitionfragility view posits that more competition among banks leads to more fragility. This “charter value” view of banking, as theoretically modeled by Marcus (1984) and Keeley (1990), sees as the sum of accounting pro…ts and the capital to asset ratio, divided by the volatility of pro…ts. As such, it indicates with how many standard deviations pro…ts can fall before capital is depleted. 4 banks as choosing the risk of their asset portfolio. Bank owners, however, have incentives to shift risks to depositors, as in a world of limited liability they only participate in the up-side part of this risk taking. In a more competitive environment with more pressures on pro…ts, banks have higher incentives to take more excessive risks, resulting in higher fragility. In systems with restricted entry and therefore limited competition, on the other hand, banks have better pro…t opportunities, capital cushions and therefore fewer incentives to take aggressive risks, with positive repercussions for …nancial stability. In addition, in more competitive environment, banks earn fewer informational rents from their relationship with borrowers, reducing their incentives to properly screen borrowers, again increasing the risk of fragility (Boot and Thakor (1993), Allen and Gale (2000), Allen and Gale (2004)). The competition-stability hypothesis, on the other hand, argues that more competitive banking systems result in more rather than less stability. Speci…cally, Boyd and De Nicolo (2005) show that lower lending rates reduce the entrepreneurs cost of borrowing and increase the success rate of entrepreneurs’investments. In addition, these …rms will refrain from excessive risk-taking to protect their increased franchise value. As a consequence, banks will face lower credit risk on their loan portfolio in more competitive markets, which should lead to increased banking sector stability. However, more recent extensions of the Boyd and De Nicolo (2005) model that allow for imperfect correlation in loan defaults (MartinezMiera and Repullo (2010); Hakenes and Schnabel (2007)) show that the relationship between competition and risk is U-shaped. Hence, the impact of an increase in competition can go either way, depending on other factors. Wagner (2010) extends the Boyd and De Nicolo (2005) model and allows for risk choices made by borrowers as well as banks. If lending rates decline due to more competition, banks have less to lose in case a borrower defaults. Hence, a bank may …nd it optimal to switch to …nancing riskier projects4 , which overturns the Boyd and De Nicolo (2005) 4 Other authors have also shown that more intense competition may induce banks to (i) switch to more risky, opaque borrowers (Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2004)), and (ii) acquire less information on borrowers (Hauswald and Marquez (2006)). 5 results. The standard response to con‡icting theoretical predictions is to let the data speak. Numerous authors have used di¤erent samples, risk measures and competition proxies to discriminate between the competition-fragility and competition-stability view.5 Empirical studies for speci…c countries – many if not most for the U.S. – have not come to conclusive evidence for an either stability-enhancing or stability-undermining role of competition. The cross-country literature has found that more concentrated banking systems are less likely to su¤er a systemic banking crisis as are more competitive banking systems (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2006); Schaeck, Cihak, and Wolfe (2009)). There seems also evidence that banks in more competitive banking systems hold more capital, thus compensating for potentially higher risk they are taking (Schaeck and Cihak (2010a), Berger, Klapper, and Turk Ariss (2009)). A consequence of the recent theoretical extensions is that the predicted impact of competition on bank stability moved from a bipolar setting (good or bad per se) to a continuous approach (settings that are better or worse in relative terms). These models lead to new testable implications that exceed a mere assessment of the sign of the coe¢ cient of bank market power. For example, by allowing loan defaults to be imperfectly correlated, the Martinez-Miera and Repullo (2010) model and the Hakenes and Schnabel (2007) model imply that the impact of competition on risk is a¤ected by regulatory constraints on asset diversi…cation, since the latter will a¤ect the correlation structure of loan defaults. Our results suggest that an increase in competition will have a larger impact on banks’risk taking incentives in countries with stricter activity restrictions, more herding in revenue structure and unconcentrated banking markets. These …ndings are con…rmed both in cross-sectional regressions as well as when we allow for additional time-series variation in the competitionstability relationship. However, we also …nd that a large part of the cross-country variation 5 For an overview, see Beck (2008). 6 in the competition-stability relationship cannot be explained, which constitutes a challenge for further research. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses di¤erent factors that might explain the variation in the competition-stability relationship documented in Figure 1. Section 3 introduces data and methodology, while section 4 presents the main results. Section 5 presents robustness, while section 6 concludes with policy implications. 2 Competition-stability relationship - theoretical considerations We argue that country-speci…c features may a¤ect the existing empirical evidence on the relationship between competition and stability via three possible channels. First, a certain type of regulation may limit the extent to which banks can or will engage in riskier activities if their franchise values are eroded. For example, regulatory capital requirements should limit the extent to which banks can follow risk-taking incentives if banks’charter value is eroded. Second, country-speci…c characteristics may also a¤ect the adverse selection problem that banks face if they charge higher loan rates. For example, lending relationships or credit registries may reduce the likelihood that entrepreneurs will chose riskier project in response to higher loan rates. Third, institutional characteristics may a¤ect the proportion of systematic and idiosyncratic risk in loan defaults and may make it hence more likely that the empirical data favor one theory over the other. For example, regulatory constraints on asset, revenue or geographical diversi…cation may make it more likely that loan defaults are highly correlated and hence lead to the empirical outcome that competition is good for …nancial stability. More speci…cally, let de- note the estimated e¤ect of bank market power on stability. This point estimate is in‡uenced by three factors: CF > 0; CS < 0; p(CF ) 2 [0; 1] where 7 CF denotes the stability welfare gains of a unit increase in market power (competition-fragility hypothesis), denotes the CS stability loss as a result of a unit increase in market power (competition-stability hypothesis) and p(CF ) indicates how likely it is that one theory dominates over the other. We conjecture that = p(CF ) CF + (1 p(CF )) CS . Our conjecture is that the regulatory environment, strength of supervision and the institutional framework of a country a¤ect CF ; CS and p(CF ). More speci…cally, let x denote the speci…c feature under investigation. A change in x (or two samples with di¤erent x) can lead to a di¤erent estimated impact of market power on stability via three di¤erent channels: @ @p(CF ) = @x @x CF @p(CF ) @x CS + p(CF ) @ CF @x + (1 p(CF )) @ CS @x The relative strength of each of these three channels may explain why di¤erent studies obtain di¤erent results in terms of sign and magnitude. That is, certain country-speci…c features may make the assumption and prediction of a given theoretical model more realistic. In the remainder of this section, we describe which country-speci…c features may play a role and why. We also introduce speci…c measures that capture these di¤erent market-speci…c characteristics. 2.1 Herding A …rst important market characteristic that can in‡uence the relationship between competition and stability is covariation of banks’behavior, also known as herding. Acharya and Yorulmazer (2007) and ? show that the supervisory decision to intervene a failing bank is subject to an implicit too-many-to-fail problem: when the number of bank failures is large, the regulator …nds it ex-post optimal to bail out some or all failed banks. This gives banks incentives to herd and increases the risk that many banks may fail together. Hence, herding behavior may also a¤ect banks’incentive to increase risk-taking in response to an increase in competition. Bank activity herding is measured by a heterogeneous banking system indicator that measures whether there are substantial di¤erences among di¤erent …nancial institutions within a country. It is calculated 8 as the within country standard deviation of the non-interest income share. If all banks in a country have a similar business model (either voluntarily or forced by regulation), the indicator will be low. When bank activities are highly correlated across banks, a rise in competition will do more damage to a banks franchise value since they do not have any other activities to fall back on. Thus, we can hypothesize that competition will have a stronger impact on bank risk CF behavior in more homogeneous banking systems, i.e. @ @x > 0. It is important to note in this context that we do not relate the actual activity structure of banks to the relationship between competition and stability, but rather the variation in activity structure within a market. We also look at herding in terms of risk taking behavior (systemic risk). If a majority of banks has a high risk appetite, it is very well possible that other banks feel the pressure to take on more risk due to the herding incentives described above. Therefore, we hypothesize that banks operating in an environment with a high risk taking standard, will have a stronger incentive to increase risk taking when competition changes. 2.2 Market structure A second important market characteristics that might in‡uence the relationship between competition and stability is the structure of the market. Martinez-Miera and Repullo (2010) and Hakenes and Schnabel (2007) show that a lower correlation of loan defaults makes it more likely that …ercer competition harms stability. A bank’s potential to reduce the correlation of its loan portfolio and other revenues is clearly a¤ected by restrictions on functional or geographical diversi…cation. If x is a proxy for diversi…cation, we conjecture that @p(CF ) @x > 0. Market concentration, measured by the Hirschmann-Her…ndahl index, may also play a role in assessing the strength of the competition-stability relationship. While these measures are not good proxies for competition6 , market concentration may play an important role in 6 See Claessens and Laeven (2004). 9 determining the relationship between competition and stability. Fewer banks in the economy (more concentrated banking markets) make supervision more e¤ective and accurate. If bank supervisors have to monitor fewer banks, they may observe malpractices (risk-shifting, loan portfolio concentration) in a more timely fashion. According to Allen and Gale (2000), countries with a larger number of banks (such as the US) are, ceteris paribus, more likely to support the competition-fragility view compared to banking sectors dominated by fewer larger banks (such as Canada), i.e. @ CF @x < 0 where x stands for the degree of concentration. Moreover, with fewer banks in the system, entrepreneurs may behave more prudently as they have fewer outside options when they default on their loans, which raises the franchise value of the bank. On the other hand, the lower the number of banks in a country, the more they will be interconnected, which may again encourage risk-taking behavior if banks perceive themselves as too-important-to fail, i.e. @ CF @x > 0. The e¤ect of market structure on the competition-stability relationship is therefore a priori ambiguous. 2.3 Regulatory and supervisory framework A third group of country traits that in‡uence the relationship between competition and stability consists of regulations designed to protect bank charter values and to prevent risk-seeking behavior if charters are eroded. High capital levels reduce the moral hazard incentives to take aggressive risks. More stringent (risk-based) capital regulation may therefore limit the CF < 0). Hellmann, Murdock, negative in‡uence that competition may have on stability ( @ @x and Stiglitz (2000), however, show that even with capital requirements, deposit interest rate ceilings are still necessary to prevent banks from excessive risk-taking in competitive markets. Furthermore, Allen, Carletti, and Marquez (2010) show that borrowers prefer well capitalized banks, since these banks have a relatively higher incentive to monitor, which improves …rm performance. They …nd that franchise value and capital are substitute ways of providing banks with 10 monitoring incentives. Also, a recent study by Mehran and Thakor (2010) shows that there is a positive relationship between bank capital holdings and total bank value. This rise in bank value and the borrower preferences should induce a rise in bank charter value, thus lowering the banks’ risk appetite. These e¤ects allow us to hypothesize that higher capital regulation limits the negative e¤ect of competition on bank stability. In other words, the average impact of an increase in competition on bank fragility is larger in countries with weak capital regulation vis-à-vis strict capital requirement regimes. Another popular regulatory measure to increase the stability of banking systems is deposit insurance, as it reduces the risk of bank runs. On the other hand, generous deposit insurance schemes might increase moral hazard and thus increase risk-taking incentives in more competitive CF > 0 (see, e.g., Demirguc-Kunt and Kane (2002)). environments, i.e. @ @x E¤ective banking supervision can be important for several reasons. First, monitoring banks is both costly and di¢ cult for both depositors and shareholders, which can lead to suboptimal bank risk behavior. Secondly, bank failures may be very costly, due to the crucial role banks play within the economic system. Taking these points into account, more e¤ective supervision should provide incentives to limit bank risk taking and thus could soften the e¤ect of competition on risk taking. On the other hand, Boot and Thakor (1993) show that supervisors may pursue self interest, which may lead to suboptimal actions. We integrate two supervisory variables into our analysis, a dummy that indicates whether there is more than one supervisor and an external governance indicator. The e¤ect of having multiple supervisors is not unambiguous. Kahn and Santos (2005) argue that if a single institution is responsible for di¤erent regulatory functions, it may not be able to su¢ ciently monitor all banks. Also, having multiple supervisors may lead to di¤erent supervisory approaches, which can generate useful information which would otherwise be neglected (Llewellyn (1999)). From this point of view, having multiple supervisors should reduce banks risk taking incentives. On the other hand, a single supervisory institution may 11 be preferred because it reduces the chance of taking con‡icting policy measures. Furthermore, Llewellyn (1999) argues that a single authority could prevent gaps in the regulation that could arise when there are multiple supervisors and that having multiple supervisors could lead to supervisory arbitrage, thus relaxing the overall supervision. The empirical evidence on this topic is rather scarce. The only study that extensively focuses on the number of supervisors is Barth, Dopico, Nolle, and Wilcox (2002) who …nd evidence for the supervisory arbitrage theory when there are multiple supervisors. The external governance indicator measures the strength of external auditors, …nancial statement transparency and accounting practices and the existence of external ratings, thus the degree of potential market discipline. Having a wide range of private control mechanisms such as external audit and external ratings should dampen the risk incentives of a bank. 2.4 Institutional and …nancial development A fourth set of country traits that can in‡uence the competition-stability relationship is the institutional framework and …nancial system structure in which banks operate. First, we consider the contractual framework. Loan defaults can arise if a borrower is unable or unwilling to repay her loan. In the latter case, contract enforcement possibilities will be of great importance for banks. If a borrower knows that a bank will have to go through numerous procedures, wait for several weeks/months or simply has to pay large fees to enforce a contract, she will have a greater incentive to evade the loan repayment. A part of the Boyd and De Nicolo (2005) explanation of the competition-stability view relies on the fact that lower loan rates will reduce the entrepreneurs’borrowing cost and thus will increase the success rate of his project, which lowers the loan default probability. However, when operating in countries with protracted contract enforcement procedures, the entrepreneur has a counteracting incentive to repay his loan, independent of his success rate. Thus, we expect that a change in competition will be more 12 harmful to stability when operating in a country with low credit enforcement standards. In other words, a rise in credit enforcement reduces the risk-shifting incentives of entrepreneurs, CS > 0. i.e. @ @x Take next the credit information sharing framework. Credit registry institutions are public or private entities which collect information on the creditworthiness of borrowers. The existence of these institutions facilitates the exchange of credit information among banks and among investors. The existence of credit registers is expected to reduce both adverse selection and moral hazard problems that are inherent on being in the lending business. Pagano and Jappelli (1993) show that information sharing lowers adverse selection problems by lowering the selection cost for lenders. Kallberg and Udell (2003) con…rm these …ndings when studying private information exchanges in the U.S.. They …nd that private credit registry information is valuable in assessing borrower quality, after controlling for information that would be available to a single institution. Information sharing also tends to reduce moral hazard incentives through reputation e¤ects (see, e.g. Diamond (1989)). As borrowers realize that it will be hard to get a loan at another institution when they default on their current loan, they will have a stronger incentive to repay and they will choose safer project (Padilla and Pagano (2000), Vercammen (1995)). Furthermore, Houston, Lin, Lin, and Ma (2010) show for a sample of nearly 2400 banks in 69 countries that greater information sharing leads to higher bank pro…ts and lowers bank risk. This leads us to hypothesize that countries with better information sharing systems will encounter smaller e¤ects on stability when competition changes, since better information systems increases a banks’franchise value and will lower the entrepreneurs’incentive to take more risk. Finally, we consider …nancial structure and, more speci…cally, competition for banks coming from …nancial markets. More developed stock markets make it easier for …rms to switch between bank-based and market-based funding. This could lead to an additional e¤ect of a change in competition on bank risk behavior. As mentioned above, Boyd and De Nicolo (2005) show that 13 a higher loan interest rate (due to lower competition) leads to a higher loan default probability. Martinez-Miera and Repullo (2010) add that, when loans are not perfectly correlated, higher interest rates also raise pro…ts on non-defaulting loans. In countries with strong developed capital markets, however, …rms will have the possibility to substitute loans with market-based funding, thus lowering the total amount of loans and bank pro…t. This leads us to hypothesize that, ceteris paribus, it is more likely to …nd positive e¤ects of competition on bank stability in countries with well developed …nancial markets. 3 Data and methodology This section consists of two parts. First, we describe the sample composition and data sources. Next, we explain how we allow for a country-level variation in the estimated impact of competition on stability. In this section, we also describe how we compute the bank-speci…c measures of soundness and market power. 3.1 Data sources We combine several data sources. We obtain information on banks’ balance sheet and income statement from Bankscope. Bankscope is a database compiled by Fitch/Bureau Van Dijck that contains information on banks around the globe, based on publicly available data-sources. Moreover, the information in the database is harmonized and provided in a global format7 that facilitates the international comparison of banks’…nancial statements. Admittedly, in general this comes at the cost of losing detailed information. However, this is not an issue for the information we need in our analysis. The period of analysis is 1994-2006, and hence is not contaminated by the exceptional events of the 2007-09 global …nancial crisis8 . If banks report information at the 7 As of April 2009, the global format is replaced by the ’Fitch Universal Format on Bankscope’. 8 The time period is mainly determined by the availability of the country-speci…c characteristics. In addition, it spans the period before Basel II was implemented. As such, the change in capital regulation does not a¤ect our 14 consolidated level, we delete the unconsolidated entries of the group from the sample to avoid double counting. We apply a number of selection criteria to arrive at our sample. First, we exclude countries for which we have information on less than 50 bank-year observations. Second, we limit our analysis to commercial, saving and cooperative banks. Third, we delete banks that report information for less than three consecutive years, as our risk measure is computed over rolling windows of three years. Fourth, we drop bank-year observations that do not have data available on basic variables drop. Subsequently, we winsorize all variables at the 1 percent level to mitigate the impact of outliers and to enhance robustness of the standard errors. While most of the bank-speci…c variables are ratios, variables in levels (such as size) are expressed in 2007 US dollars using a GDP de‡ator. The bank-speci…c data are linked to various country-level datasets that contain information on the regulatory framework, strength of supervision and other institutional features. More speci…cally, we employ data from the three vintages (2000, 2003 and 2007) of the Bank regulation and supervision dataset compiled by the World Bank (Barth, Caprio, and Levine (2008)). Additional information is obtained from the Heritage Foundation,the World Development Indicators and the Doing Business database. A detailed list of the variables used and the database from which they are collected can be found in Table 13. Filtering the bank-speci…c database and matching it with the country-level datasets yields a sample of banks from 62 countries. The sample consists of a mix of developed and developing countries (see Table ??). 3.2 Empirical framework In the literature, there are two main approaches to assessing the relationship between competition and stability: a single country or multiple country setup. In a cross-country setup, proxies measure of risk. Note also that by looking at a cross-country setting over the period 1994-2006, we do have other crisis episodes in the sample. 15 of market power at the bank- or country-level are related to bank soundness (in a linear or quadratic speci…cation). The sign of the coe¢ cient(s) then indicate whether competition helps or harms stability (or whether there is a turning point at which there is a sign reversal). These studies provide insight into the average relationship between competition and stability for the set of countries under investigation (e.g.: developing countries as in Turk Ariss (2010), developed countries as in Berger, Klapper, and Turk Ariss (2009), the European Union as in Schaeck and Cihak (2010b)), while controlling for other country-speci…c factors such as macro-economic conditions, regulation and supervision. However, single country studies (such as Keeley (1990), Salas and Saurina (2003), Jimenez, Lopez, and Saurina Salas (2010), Boyd, De Nicolo, and Jalal (2006)) document a large degree of variation in the competition-stability relationship. This indicates that these other country-speci…c factors may not only have a level e¤ect but also a slope e¤ect. Hence, it is not only important to control for the impact of these factors on risk but also on how they shape the competition-stability relationship. For example, activity restrictions (i.e. allowing banks to enter real estate, insurance or underwriting) may not only a¤ect the aggregate level of risk, but may also in‡uence the extent to which loan market power a¤ect bank risk-taking incentives. Put di¤erently, these variables may also determine whether it is more likely to …nd support for the franchise value paradigm compared to the risk-shifting hypothesis or vice versa. This results in the following setup: Riski;j;t = c + j Competitioni;j;t 1 + j Xi;j;t 1 + Zj;t + "i;j;t (1) In this setup, the indices i; j ; t stand respectively for bank, country and time. The impact of competition (as well as any other bank-speci…c variable, Xi;j;t ) on risk is allowed to vary at the country level. This is denoted by giving the corresponding (vector of) coe¢ cient(s) a j subscript. The vector of bank-speci…c variables, Xi;t 1, characterizes a bank’s business model. In particular, we include proxies for the funding structure (share of wholesale funding in total funding), asset 16 (loans to assets ratio) and revenue mix (share of non-interest income in total income) as well bank size (natural logarithm of total assets), credit risk (loan loss provisions to interest income) and asset growth. In addition, we include specialization dummies to allow for di¤erent intercepts for commercial banks, bank holding companies, saving banks and cooperatives. Summary statistics on the control variables that determine bank soundness are in the upper part of Table 1. In addition, time-varying country-speci…c characteristics may also a¤ect bank soundness are included in the vector Zj;t . We hypothesize that j can be modelled as a function of (a subset of) these country-speci…c factors. To gain insight in the potential drivers of heterogeneity in , we take a two-step approach. In a …rst step, we relate bank market power to a measure of bank soundness. This relationship is assessed at the country level. More speci…cally, for each country in our sample, we estimate the following equation: Riski;t = c + Competitioni;t 1 + Xi;t 1 + vt + "i;t (2) Including time …xed e¤ects and estimating this equation country by country creates many advantages. First, we allow for the maximum extent of heterogeneity in the competition-stability trade-o¤ across countries. Second, the time dummies di¤er in each country regression and hence indirectly capture the level e¤ect of country-speci…c regulation or the business cycle on bank risk. In the second step, we will explore which country-speci…c variables explain the heterogeneity in the estimated 3.3 j s. Indicators of market power and bank soundness In this subsection, we describe how we measure competition, discuss the correlation with other measures of competition and introduce our indicator of bank soundness. 17 3.3.1 The Lerner index: measure of pricing power For our analysis, we need a measure of market power that varies at the bank level rather than a competition or concentration proxy at the country level. The Lerner index is an obvious candidate as it captures the extent to which banks can increase the marginal price beyond the marginal cost. Conditional on having an estimate of the marginal price and cost, we can construct the Lerner index for each bank and each year, as follows: Lerneri;t = Pi;t M Ci;t Pi;t (3) where Pi;t is proxied by the ratio of total operating income to total assets. As banks have the opportunity to expand their activities into non-interest generating activities, we include both interest and non-interest revenue. The marginal cost, M Ci;t , is derived from a translog cost function. As Berger, Klapper, and Turk Ariss (2009), we model the total operating cost of running the bank as a function of a single, aggregate output proxy, Qi;t , and three input prices, j wi;t , with j 2 f1; 2; 3g. More speci…cally, we estimate: ln Ci;t = 0+ 1 ln Qi;t + 3 X 2 (ln Q ) + 2 i;t j=1 3 3 X X j ln w + j i;t j=1 k=1 3 X j k ln w ln w + j;k i;t i;t j j ln wi;t ln Qi;t +vt +"i;t j=1 (4) We also include time dummies to capture technological progress as well as varying business cycle conditions, as well as a bank specialization dummy. Homogeneity of degree one in input 3 3 X X prices is obtained by imposing the restrictions: = 1; j j = 0 and 8 k 2 f1; 2; 3g : j=1 3 X j;k j=1 = 0. Marginal cost is then obtained as follows: j=1 M Ci;t 0 1 j 2 X wi;t Ci;t @ @Ci;t = b 1 + 2b 2 ln Qi;t + bj ln 3 A = @Qi;t Qi;t wi;t j=1 18 (5) in which Ci;t measures total operating costs (interest expenses, personnel and other administrative or operating costs), Qi;t represents a proxy for bank output or total assets for bank i at time t. The three input prices capture the price of …xed assets, the price of labor and the price of borrowed funds. They are constructed as respectively the share of other operating and administrative expenses to total assets, the ratio of personnel expenses to total assets and the ratio of interest expenses to total deposits and money market funding. Following Berger, Klapper, and Turk Ariss (2009), Equation (4) is estimated separately for each country in the sample to re‡ect potentially di¤erent technologies. <Insert Table 1 around here> Table 1 presents summary statistics on the variables needed to construct the Lerner index as well as the estimated Lerner index. The average Lerner index at the country level is 10%, but varies across countries, from 3.3.2 3:8% in Uruguay to 22:0% in Denmark (see Table 14). The Z-Score: measure of bank soundness In our analysis, bank risk is measured using the Z-score. The Z-score measures the distance from insolvency (Roy (1952)) and is calculated as Zi;t = ROAi;t + (E=A)i;t (ROA)i;t where ROA is return on assets, E=A denotes the equity to asset ratio and (6) (ROA) is the standard deviation of return on assets. While in large parts of the literature the volatility of pro…ts is computed over the full sample period, we use a three-year rolling time window for the standard deviation of ROA to allow for variation in the denominator of the Z-score. This approach avoids that the Z-scores are exclusively driven by variation in the levels of capital and pro…tability (Schaeck and Cihak (2010b)). Moreover, given the unbalanced nature of our panel dataset, it avoids that the denominator is computed over di¤erent window lengths for di¤erent 19 banks. The Z-score can be interpreted as the number of standard deviations by which returns would have to fall from the mean to wipe out all equity in the bank (Boyd and Runkle (1993)). A higher Z-score implies a lower probability of insolvency, providing a more direct measure of soundness than, for example, simple leverage measures. Because the Z-score is highly skewed, we use the natural logarithm of Z-score to smooth out higher values9 . Table 1 shows that the average value of ln(Z-score) slightly exceeds four with a standard deviation of 1:15. Our indicator of market power is signi…cantly correlated with the Z-score and other indicators of competition, but also with indicators of market concentration. Table 2 presents correlations on the country-year level between the Z-score, the Lerner index if market power as well as bank and country-level indicators of competition and market structure. The Lerner index is positively and signi…cantly correlated with the Z-score, consistent with Figure 1. The Lerner index is negatively and signi…cantly correlated with the average market share of banks in a country and year, while there is no signi…cant correlation with the number of banks. The Lerner index is higher for more concentrated banking markets, as measured by the Her…ndahl index. Interestingly, there is no signi…cant correlation between the Lerner index of market power and two other industry-level behavioral indicators of bank competition, the H-Statistics and the Boone index. 4 The competition-stability relationship: explaining cross9 Others have used the transformation ln(1+Z-score) to avoid truncating the dependent variable at zero. We take the natural logarithm after winsorizing the data at the 1% level. As none of the Z-scores is lower than zero after winsorizing, this approach is similar, save for a rescaling, to the former approach and winsorizing after the transformation. 20 country variation 4.1 The competition-stability relationship: Cross-country heterogeneity In the Introduction, we mentioned that the full sample unconditional correlation between the Lerner index and the Z-score is positive (0:31), but that this number hides a substantial amount of cross-country variation (see Figure 1). Using a regression framework, we show that this relationship also holds when conditioning on other variables . Following common practice in the literature, we regress the bank soundness measure on the Lerner index and a wide range of control variables using our total sample. The results are presented in table 3. <Insert Table 3 around here> The …rst column shows OLS estimates, whereas the second column are IV (2SLS) regression results. In the second column, we take into account that market power may be endogenous. The instruments are loan growth and lagged values of the Lerner index. We employ the panel structure of the database and control for …xed heterogeneity at the country and time level by including country and time …xed e¤ects. The standard errors are robust and clustered at the bank level. Moreover, to avoid that our results are driven by countries that are overrepresented in our sample, we weigh each variable with the inverse of the number of banks in the country. Doing so, we give equal weight to each country. We again …nd a positive and signi…cant e¤ect of a change in market power on bank stability. This result is in line with existing literature that also uses the Lerner index as a market power proxy (see, e.g. Berger, Klapper, and Turk Ariss (2009)). However, as already mentioned in the introduction, our interest is less on arguing that competition is good or bad, but rather on uncovering which country characteristics make the impact better of worse. Therefore, it is crucial to show that the regression-based methods also indicate that there is a substantial degree of heterogeneity. 21 <Insert Figure 2 around here> Figure 2 is very similar to Figure 1 of the introduction. The correlation between the conditional and unconditional correlation is 0:69 and highly signi…cant. Both bar charts show that the unconditional and conditional correlations are positive in most countries. In Figure 2, the height of the bars shows the magnitude of the coe¢ cient of the Lerner index when estimating Equation (2) for each country separately. The bars are sorted from low to high and the country labels are mentioned on the X-axis. The coe¢ cients that are signi…cantly di¤erent from zero have a lighter shade. The average of the 62 estimated coe¢ cients equals 0.982, which resembles the full sample coe¢ cient. Hence, on average, it seems that the franchise value paradigm dominates the risk-shifting hypothesis. In response to an increase in market power, banks will behave more prudently to protect their monopoly rents that create a larger franchise value. Or vice versa, an increase in competition increases banks’ appetite for risk-taking. However, there is a large amount of heterogeneity in the competition-stability relationship. The standard deviation of the coe¢ cient across the 62 countries is 1.464. A quick look at the country labels on the X-axis also reveals that it is not just a developed versus developing countries story or that regions exhibit similar behavior. In the remainder of this section, we will empirically explore what drives this high cross-country variation in the competition-stability relationship. 4.2 A binary classi…cation approach Our goal is to shed light on the underlying factors that drive this heterogeneous impact. Uncovering which institutional features drive the cross-sectional variation in b j will allow us to identify which banking sectors will not be harmed (or harmed less) by more intense banking competi- tion. To assess the impact of regulatory, supervision and institutional features on the estimated competition-stability trade-o¤, we …rst classify the sample countries into two distinct groups ac- 22 cording to the median value of each such speci…c feature. We perform two sorts of tests10 , which di¤er in their treatment of potential cross-country di¤erences in the impact of bank-speci…c characteristics on bank risk. More speci…cally, we employ a SEPARATE and POOLED approach. Both approaches di¤er in the amount of heterogeneity they allow in the relationship between control variables and bank risk. In the SEPARATE test methodology, we employ t-tests to compare the di¤erence in magnitude of the competition-stability relationship across the two groups. More speci…cally, we perform t-tests on two measures. On the one hand, we look at variation in the (unconditional) correlation between the Z-score and the lagged Lerner index. On the other hand, we also estimate Equation (2) separately for each country, and then average the estimated values within each group formed based on a particular institutional characteristic. The POOLED methodology estimates Equation (2) across all banks from countries with a speci…c institutional feature. We thereby impose common slopes (both on the Lerner index and the control variables) within each group. For example, we estimate equation (2) across all countries with weak activity restrictions, and then across all banks in the strong activity restriction countries. We thus estimate a single coe¢ cient for each group of countries11 , and test whether the coe¢ cients di¤er between the two groups of countries. To compare the impact of the Lerner index on bank stability across the two groups, we employ Chow tests. The POOLED approach is implemented using OLS as well as IV(2SLS). According to Oztekin and Flannery (2008), the separate and pooled methodologies each have its own merits. Averaging individual country regressions in the 1 0 Oztekin and Flannery (2008) perform a similar kind of analysis to examine how country-speci…c features a¤ect the adjustment speed at which …rms converge to their target leverage. 1 1 Larger countries with more banks may be overrepresented in a particular group. For example, the majority of banks within the sample operate in the US. On the one hand, could this lead to US-biased results, on the other hand does it make a fair comparison with the separate approach invalid. Therefore, we give equal weight to each country in the pooled approach. The weight that each individual bank observation gets is proportional to 1=ni , where ni equals the number of observations for country i. Moreover, we include time and country …xed e¤ects and cluster the standard errors at the bank level. 23 SEPARATE method allows for full heterogeneity in parameter estimates and error variances. However, estimating Equation (2) for countries with few banks might also yield noisy coe¢ cient estimates. The POOLED method assumes slope and error variance homogeneity across countries, raising the possibility that the gains from pooling would outweigh any costs imposed by ignoring the inherent heterogeneity in the slope estimates. Since we believe that neither method is superior, we document our results using both approaches. Table 5 consists of two panels. The …rst panel corresponds to the separate approach, whereas the second panel contains the results of the pooled approach. Summary statistics on the countryspeci…c variables are reported in Table 4. Variable de…nitions and sources are reported where they occur for the …rst time in the text. The country-speci…c variables are obtained from various sources and may vary at a di¤erent level. Some variables are (almost) constant over time, other vary by country and over time. Moreover, not all variables are available for all countries or all time periods. <Insert Table 4 around here> In Table 4, the summary statistics of the country-speci…c variables are categorized in four groups. The results on the SEPARATE and POOLED tests will be described in a similar order. 4.2.1 Herding As discussed above, we use two proxies of herding. The heterogeneous banking system indicator measures whether there are substantial revenue di¤erences among di¤erent …nancial institutions within a country. It is calculated as the within country standard deviation of the non-interest income share. If all banks in a country have a similar business model (either voluntarily or forced by regulation), the indicator will be low. A higher value indicates that the banking system is more diverse. In heterogeneous banking systems, an increase in competition is less detrimental for bank risk compared to homogeneous banking systems. A second indicator of the too-many- 24 to-fail problem is the aggregate Z-score. This variable is a proxy of systemic risk. Lower values of the aggregate Z-score points to an overall reduction in banking sector soundness and larger scope for herding as the likelihood of joint failures is larger in unstable banking sectors. The results in Table 5 indicate that competition will do more harm when banks’activities are highly correlated as they mimic their rivals’business model12 . We also …nd signi…cant and robust evidence that banks operating in less stable banking systems will gamble more in response to an increase in competition compared to stable banking sectors, in which it is more likely that default will be an idiosyncratic event. Herding thus exacerbates the negative impact of competition on stability. 4.2.2 Market structure Market structure consists of several di¤erent dimensions. First, we look at whether overall activity restrictions limit the types of banks in the country. Therefore we include an activity restriction index, taken from the World Bank’s “Bank regulation and supervision”database (Barth, Caprio, and Levine (2008)), which measures the degree to which banks are permitted to engage in feebased activities related to securities, insurance and real estate rather than more traditional interest spread-based activities. Lower values of the index indicate that no restrictions are placed on this type of diversi…cation by banks and higher values indicate that such diversi…cation is prohibited. Next, we look at the Hirschmann-Her…ndahl index (based on total assets) as a proxy of bank market concentration13 . Larger values denote a more disperse distribution of market shares and hence higher concentration. Finally, we also check whether the existence of entry barriers, as a proxy of the contestability of the market, a¤ect the strength of the competition1 2 We also tried a similar measure of herding on the funding side, which, however, does not seem to matter for the competition-stability relationship. 1 3 We also looked at a Hirschmann-Her…ndahl index based on total loans and a CR3 ratio as concentration proxies. Both indicators lead to similar results as for the HHI based on total assets. 25 stability relationship. Entry barriers is an index measuring the degree to which applications to receive a banking licence have been denied over the past …ve years. Higher values of the index indicate greater stringency, hence less competition. The results in Table 5 indicate that the impact of competition on bank risk is larger in banking sectors that face higher restrictions. The di¤erences are signi…cant in all test set-ups (unconditional versus conditional, separate versus pooled). An increase in competition (lower Lerner index) will lead, ceteris paribus, to a much larger reduction in Z-scores for banks operating in countries with stricter restrictions on di¤erent …nancial activities. If we classify the countries in our sample in a low and high concentrated group, we …nd that the positive impact of market power on stability is larger in concentrated banking systems. Put di¤erently, from a …nancial stability perspective, an increase in loan market competition is more detrimental in countries with more disperse bank market structures. This is in line with Allen and Gale (2000). In the separate and pooled approaches, the mean of the high group is lower than the mean of the low group. The means are signi…cantly di¤erent in the two groups for the classi…cation based on the Her…ndahl index. Finally, using the fraction of entry applications denied to classify countries in a low and high entry barriers group yields less stable results in terms of signi…cance. The pooled and separate approach yield opposite conclusions. 4.2.3 Regulatory and supervisory structure To test the hypothesis that capital regulation reduces the negative impact of more competition on stability, we divide the countries in the sample in two groups based on a capital stringency index. The capital stringency index checks whether there are explicit requirements regarding the amount of capital that a bank should have. A higher index indicates greater stringency. In addition to capital regulation, deposit insurance schemes have been designed to protect depositors from excessive risk-taking by banks. Deposit insurance coverage is proxied by deposit insurance 26 coverage relative to GDP per capita. This variable taken from the Deposit Insurance Around the World database of the World Bank (Demirguc-Kunt, Karacaovali, and Laeven (2005)). Banking supervision is captured by an external governance index and a dummy that equals one if there are multiple supervisors in a country. The external governance index allows us to check the in‡uence of private monitoring mechanism, while the supervisory dummy gives more info on the structure of public supervision. The results in Table 5 show that the average unconditional correlation between the Lerner index and the Z-score is larger in the set of countries with a capital stringency index below the mean. Hence, an increase in competition is more harmful for bank stability in countries with weak capital regulation. However, the averages are not signi…cantly di¤erent across both groups. Hence, we …nd no support for the theories that predict that stricter capital requirements are a substitute for franchise values and will prevent to take on excessive risks when they are faced with more intense competition. Looking at deposit insurance coverage relative to GDP per capita, it is clear that countries with more generous deposit insurance systems face a worse competitionstability trade-o¤. As a more generous deposit insurance system reduces the e¤ectiveness of outside monitors, banks have a larger incentive to gamble in response to a shrinking Lerner index. When we divide the countries in our sample in a high and low group based on the external governance index, we see that countries with weak external monitoring mechanisms react stronger to changes in competition. Thus, an increase in loan market competition will be more harmful for bank stability in countries with a low focus on private monitoring. On the other hand, having multiple bank supervisors leads to a stronger impact of loan market competition on bank risk taking behavior, while the impact of competition is far milder when there is only one supervisor. Multiple supervisors may lead to coordination problems if they have supervisory responsibilities over di¤erent activities. For both measures, the four approaches yield di¤erences of consistent magnitude, though the statistical signi…cance at the conventional levels is not achieved across all 27 methods. 4.2.4 Institutional and …nancial development We hypothesized that variables capturing the extent to which information on borrowers (and defaults) are shared and the cost of enforcing contracts may a¤ect the risk-shifting incentives of entrepreneurs. We use a dummy to capture whether there is a public or a private registry present in a country, as well as an indicator of credit information depth. This variable captures the di¤erence in information content between the registers in di¤erent countries, since some of them only collect limited information on large borrowers, while others have extensive information on a whole range of borrowers and their characteristics (Miller (2003)). The index ranges between 0 and 6, with a higher value indicating that there is more information available.. Both variables are based on the Doing Business database from the World Bank. From the same database we also use the a proxy measuring the contract enforcement cost in a country, thus a negative indicator of the e¢ ciency of the contractual framework. Furthermore, we use stock market turnover , i.e. the ratio of stocks traded to stocks listed, as indicator of …nancial market development. Finally, we consider a sample split according to GDP per capita, the most general indicator of economic and institutional development. Table 5 shows that the split up based on the credit registry dummy does not lead to signi…cant di¤erences in the competition-stability trade-o¤. Also, the depth of credit information and the cost of contract enforcement do not play a decisive role in the competition-stability relationship. The stock market turnover variable, on the other hand, leads to signi…cant and consistent …ndings over the four methods. Our results show that banks in countries with a high stock market turnover tend to have higher risk taking incentives when there is a rise in competition. Finally, we …nd no signi…cant di¤erence in the competition-stability relationship across countries with di¤erent levels of economic development, as measured by GDP per capita. 28 4.3 Competition-stability relationship: a continuous approach The binary classi…cation approach provides evidence that many country-speci…c characteristics may have an e¤ect on the competition-stability trade-o¤. One could still wonder (i) to what extent these variables capture di¤erent information and do they still have an impact when they are simultaneously controlled for, and (ii) whether the relationship is con…rmed using all the variability in the proxy (rather than creating high and low groups) . In this section, we provide further insight into these issues. Based on the results reported in Table 5, we select a number of variables to include in a continuous rather than binary analysis. Country-speci…c variables are only included if they satisfy the following criteria: (i) they have to be signi…cant in the IV(2SLS) case, (ii) they have to be signi…cant in more than half of the test setups in Table 5. This leaves us with Herding - Revenues, Activity Restrictions, entry applications denied, HHI, Multiple Supervisors, and Stock Market Turnover ratio. Table 6 provides information on the correlation matrix of these six variables as well as the (un)conditional correlation coe¢ cients at the country level. The binary approach showed that these characteristics potentially play an important role in the competition-stability relationship. The correlation table con…rms these …ndings and also provides information on how these countryspeci…c variables are correlated with each other. Table 7 provides information on estimation results of regressions of the following form: Riski;j;t = c + ( 0 + j Zj;t ) Competitioni;j;t 1 + j Xi;j;t 1 + vt + vj + "i;j;t (7) where Zj;t is either just one of the above-mentioned country-speci…c characteristics or a vector containing all of them. The …rst column shows the outcome for the baseline regression at the bank level, i.e. when regressing our stability measure (Z-score) on the Lerner index, a group of bank-speci…c control variables and GDP per capita. In each subsequent column, we add an interaction term of the Lerner index with a country-speci…c characteristic. In the last column, we 29 show the result when we add all interaction terms simultaneously. For ease of comparability of the economic signi…cance, all country-speci…c variables have been normalized to have zero mean and unit variance. In the characteristic-by-characteristic regressions, each of the interaction terms is signi…cant (except the systemic risk proxy) with the expected sign. As we selected the variables based on their signi…cance in the binary approach, this is not surprising. When exploiting all of the heterogeneity rather than only classifying them into a high or low group, we reinforce the previous …ndings. We …nd strong and convincing multivariate evidence that competition is more harmful for stability in countries where (i) banks herd more in terms of revenue structure, (ii) there are more restrictions on the permissible range of activities, (iii) they operate in less concentrated markets, (iv) deposit insurance is more generous and (v) stock markets are more liquid. The last columns show that almost all results hold when they are simultaneously controlled for. The high correlation of deposit insurance with Activity Restrictions and HHI also in‡ates its standard errors. Interestingly, the absolute value of the coe¢ cients of the signi…cant variables varies in magnitude (between 0:14 and 0:27). As we normalized the variables, there seems to be an important e¤ect in economic terms, and the importance varies with the variable under consideration. The coe¢ cient on the Lerner index without interaction is 1:04. A one standard deviation increase in one of these variables hence leads to a 13% to 25% change in the impact of competition on stability. 5 5.1 Additional results Time variation in the competition-stability relationship So far, our analysis has focused on the cross-country di¤erences in the relationship between competition and bank stability. In this part, we allow for additional variation over time in these country-speci…c relationships. More speci…cally, for each country we regress our bank 30 stability measure (Z-score) on the Lerner index, a group of bank speci…c control variables and GDP per capita, while using …ve year rolling windows. In this way, we retrieve time-varying (conditional) correlations between the Lerner index and bank stability. Since our sample period is 1994-2006, and taking into account that we lag our independent variables with one period, we get a maximum of eight country-speci…c conditional correlations. The retrieved correlations are subsequently regressed on country-speci…c variables measured at the …rst year of the …ve year windows. Table 8 displays the results for three di¤erent regression speci…cations using this setup. In the …rst column, we show the results coming from a regression of the conditional, time-varying correlations on all seven country-speci…c characteristics, while clustering the standard errors over time. In the second column, we only include those variables that are individually signi…cant in the continuous approach. Standard errors are again clustered over time. The third regression mimics the speci…cation in the last column of the previous table. The results in column 1 of Table 8 show that country characteristics explain only 24 percent of the variation in the conditional correlation coe¢ cients. Hence, after taking into account countryspeci…c characteristics (and having considered a wide range of potential drivers), there is still a lot of unexplained variation in the competition-stability relationship. If this heterogeneity is all random, this is worrying as it implies that it is di¢ cult to design an optimal regulatory setting to minimize the negative e¤ect of competition on stability. The results of this time-varying analysis largely con…rm our previous …ndings. First of all, the impact of revenue herding on stability is negative and signi…cant for two out of three speci…cations. Thus, banks in countries where the majority of the banks collect their revenues from the same type of business will respond stronger – in terms of risk behavior - to a change in competition than banks in dispersed markets. In other words, heterogeneous banking markets are more likely to support the competition-stability theorem. Furthermore, the results show that more activity restrictions have a positive and signi…cant impact on the correlation coe¢ cient. 31 Financial institutions that are allowed to become universal banks will face imperfectly correlated revenue streams, which in‡uences their reaction to a change in competition. This result is consistent over the two regression speci…cations and in line with our previous …ndings It again con…rms that the impact of competition on bank risk behavior will be larger in markets with a more concentrated bank focus. The fact that more diversi…ed banks tend to have higher charter values seems to dominate the higher risk taking incentive for diversi…ed banks due to the lower correlation in loan defaults. The third and fourth country characteristic that have a consistent signi…cant impact on bank stability is deposit insurance and stock market turnover. They are positive and signi…cant in all three speci…cations. Given that the variables are normalized, the economic impact of deposit insurance is twice as large as that of stock market turnover.. 5.2 Alternative risk measures Until now, we have used the Z-score as our preferred bank risk measure. The Z-score combines bank equity over total assets, return on assets, and the volatility of the returns to come up with a measure of bank stability. It thus combines three di¤erent risk aspects. In this part, we will look at the reaction of these three subcomponents when the level of competition changes. We are particularly interested whether the subcomponents all move in the same direction or whether there is a component overruling the other two subcomponents. Furthermore, we also look at the amount of non-performing loans as a potential alternative bank risk measure. The Table 9 con…rms our …ndings while using the alternative risk measures. The …rst column shows the standard results when using the Z-score as stability measure and regressing it on the Lerner index and a group of bank-speci…c control variables. For regression (2) to (5) we use four alternative stability measures, being non-performing loans and the three subcomponents of the Zscore. For each stability measure we perform the basic regression with country-year …xed e¤ects. When using non-performing loans as stability measure, we leave out the loan loss provisions 32 over interest income ratio as a control variable, since both variables are heavily related to each other. The results show that all subcomponents of the Z-score react in a similar way to a change in competition. A rise in market power leads to a higher equity ratio, more return on assets and lower return volatility. Furthermore, a rise in competition also leads to less non-performing loans. The results for the alternative risk measures are thus in line with the Z-score results; we again …nd consistent and signi…cant evidence in favour of the competition-fragility theorem. A rise in market power (measured by the Lerner index) leads to more stability, independent of the stability proxy we use. 5.3 Bank-variation in the competition-stability relationship So far, we have exploited cross-country and time-series variation in the competition-stability relationship. However, banks’risk-taking incentives might be also in‡uenced by their own relative position in the market. Speci…cally, we posit that failing banks have a greater incentive to exploit competition towards more aggressive risk-taking. Further, banks with a larger market-share and that therefore consider themselves too-big-to-fail might also exploit increasing competition to take more aggressive risks. This subsection assesses whether such bank-level variation exists. Table 10 shows the impact of competition on bank stability while controlling for the potential impact of failing banks. The …rst column shows our baseline competition-stability regression. In the second and the third column, we interact the Lerner index with an exit dummy. In the second regression, the exit dummy equals one in the two years before the bank leaves the sample. These banks seem to react less intense when competition changes. However, notice that this dummy does not discriminate between defaults and distressed mergers at the one hand and ’normal’ mergers or acquisitions at the other hand. Therefore, in the third regression, the exit dummy only equals one in the two years before a bank leaves the sample when the bank had a negative return on assets in that period. In this way, we only capture the banks that actually where 33 in distress before they leave the sample. The signi…cant and positive interaction term between competition and the exit dummy indicates that these banks that are in trouble before leaving the sample react more strongly to a change in competition. Thus, banks that are in distress gamble even more than others when competition rises, probably because there is not much left to loose for them. In the fourth regression, we only look at banks that did not exit the sample (Distressed Exit Dummy =0), while adding interaction terms between the Lerner index and country-speci…c characteristics that potentially in‡uence the competition-stability relationship. The results show that market power still has a positive impact on bank stability for these banks. Furthermore, as shown in our previous analysis, banks operating in a country with high activity restrictions or with a highly liquid stock market tend to react stronger to a change in competition. Table 11 shows the results for the baseline competition-stability regression while controlling for the impact of bank market share. The …rst column retakes our baseline results, while we interact the Lerner index with a bank’s market share (measured in terms of total assets) in the second regression. This allows us to check whether banks with a higher market share have an incentive to take more risk, because they can potentially see themselves as too-big-to-fail. The results indicate that there is no direct too-big-to-fail e¤ect in‡uencing the competition-stability relationship. In the third column, we do a similar exercise, but now using a market share dummy that equals one for bank with a market share that is larger than 10 percent. Again, we do not …nd a signi…cant direct e¤ect of a banks’market share on the competition-stability relationship. 6 Conclusion This paper aims to reconcile the seemingly contrasting evidence on the bank competition-bank soundness relationship. Theoretical models and empirical results o¤er con‡icting evidence. A …rst look at a worldwide sample of banks tells us that the relationship between market power and bank soundness is positive. Hence, on average, it seems that the franchise value paradigm 34 dominates the risk-shifting hypothesis. In response to an increase in market power, banks will behave more prudently to protect their monopoly rents that create a larger franchise value. Or vice versa, an increase in competition increases banks’ appetite for risk-taking. However, this full sample relationship hides a substantial amount of cross-sectional heterogeneity, with estimates ranging from negative to positive, with many countries showing insigni…cant relationships between competition and stability. We develop a framework to assess how regulation, supervision and other institutional factors may make it more likely that the data favor one theory over the other, i.e. the charter value paradigm over the risk-shifting paradigm. We show that an increase in competition will have a larger impact on banks’risk taking incentives in countries with stricter activity restrictions, more herding in revenue structure and unconcentrated banking markets. Our …ndings help in understanding the seemingly con‡icting empirical evidence. Most studies tend to …nd results in favour of the competition-fragility view. However, if one would sample banks from countries/regions with concentrated banking markets and homogeneous operations (either homogeneous because of regulatory restrictions or due to herding), obtaining the opposite …nding need not be inconsistent. Our …ndings have important policy repercussions. They suggest that activity restrictions and herding trends can exacerbate the negative impact of competition on bank stability so that regulatory reforms have to take this into account. We show that the too-many-to-fail phenomenon is worse in more competitive environments. On the other hand, capital regulations seem to have less of an in‡uence on the relationship between competition and stability, which puts the current debate on capital bu¤ers somewhat in perspective. References Acharya, Viral V., and Tanju Yorulmazer, 2007, Too many to fail–an analysis of timeinconsistency in bank closure policies, Journal of Financial Intermediation 16, 1–31. 35 Allen, Franklin, Elena Carletti, and Robert Marquez, 2010, Credit market competition and capital regulation, Review of Financial Studies , forthcoming. Allen, F., and D. Gale, 2000, Comparing …nancial systems, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. , 2004, Competition and …nancial stability, Journal of Money Credit and Banking 36, 453–480. Barth, James, Gerard Caprio, and Ross Levine, 2008, Bank regulation and supervision database (updated june 2008), World Bank. Barth, James, R., G. Dopico, Luis, E. Nolle, Daniel, and A. Wilcox, James, 2002, Bank safety and soundness and the structure of bank supervision: A cross-country analysis, International Review of Finance 3, 163–188. Beck, Thorsten, 2008, Bank competition and …nancial stability : friends or foes ?, Policy Research Working Paper Series 4656 Policy Research Working Paper Series. , Asli Demirguc-Kunt, and Ross Levine, 2006, Bank concentration, competition, and crises: First results, Journal of Banking Finance 30, 1581–1603. Berger, A. N., L. F. Klapper, and Rima Turk Ariss, 2009, Bank competition and …nancial stability, Journal of Financial Services Research 35, 99–118. Boot, Arnoud W. A., and Anjan V. Thakor, 1993, Self-interested bank regulation, The American Economic Review 83, 206–212. Boyd, John H., and Gianni De Nicolo, 2005, The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited, Journal of Finance 60, 1329–1343. , and Abu M. Jalal, 2006, Bank risk-taking and competition revisited: New theory and new evidence, IMF Working Paper No. 06/297. 36 Boyd, J. H., and D. E. Runkle, 1993, Size and performance of banking …rms - testing the predictions of theory, Journal of Monetary Economics 31, 47–67. Claessens, Stijn, and Luc Laeven, 2004, What drives bank competition? some international evidence, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 36, 563–83. Dell’Ariccia, G., and R. Marquez, 2004, Information and bank credit allocation, Journal of Financial Economics 72, 185–214. Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Enrica Detragiache, 2002, Does deposit insurance increase banking system stability? an empirical investigation, Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 1373–1406. Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Edward Kane, 2002, Deposit insurance around the globe: Where does it work?, Journal of Economic Perspectives 16, 175–195. Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, Baybars Karacaovali, and Luc Laeven, 2005, Deposit insurance around the world: A comprehensive database, Policy Research Paper , World Bank. Diamond, Douglas W., 1989, Reputation acquisition in debt markets, The Journal of Political Economy 97, 828–862. Hakenes, Hendrik, and Isabel Schnabel, 2007, Bank competition and capital regulation, http://ssrn.com/paper=965430. Hauswald, R., and R. Marquez, 2006, Competition and strategic information acquisition in credit markets, Review of Financial Studies 19, 967–1000. Hellmann, T. F., K. C. Murdock, and J. E. Stiglitz, 2000, Liberalization, moral hazard in banking, and prudential regulation: Are capital requirements enough?, American Economic Review 90, 147–165. Houston, Joel F., Chen Lin, Ping Lin, and Yue Ma, 2010, Creditor rights, information sharing and bank risk taking, Journal of Finacial Economics 96, 485–512. 37 Jayaratne, Jith, and Philip Strahan, 1998, Entry restrictions, industry evolution, and dynamic e¢ ciency: Evidence from commercial banking, Journal of Law and Economics 41, 239–273. Jimenez, Gabriel, Jose A. Lopez, and Jesus Saurina Salas, 2010, How does competition impact bank risk-taking?, Banco de Espana Working Paper No. 1005. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1582331. Kahn, Charles M., and Joao A. C. Santos, 2005, Allocating bank regulatory powers: Lender of last resort, deposit insurance and supervision, European Economic Review 49, 2107–2136. Kallberg, Jarl G., and Gregory F. Udell, 2003, The value of private sector business credit information sharing: The us case, Journal of Banking Finance 27, 449–469. Keeley, M. C., 1990, Deposit insurance, risk, and market power in banking, American Economic Review 80, 1183–1200. Llewellyn, D.T., 1999, Introduction: The institutional structure of regulatory agencies, in N.Courtis (ed.), How countries supervise their banks,insurers and securities markets. Marcus, Alan J., 1984, Deregulation and bank …nancial policy, Journal of Banking Finance 8, 557–565. Martinez-Miera, David, and Rafael Repullo, 2010, Does competition reduce the risk of bank failure?, Review of Financial Studies , forthcoming. Mehran, Hamid, and Anjan Thakor, 2010, Bank capital and value in the cross-section, Review of Financial Studies , forthcoming. Miller, Margaret J., 2003, Credit reporting systems and the international economy, The MIT Press. Oztekin, Ozde, and Mark J. Flannery, 2008, Institutional determinants of capital structure adjustment speeds, http://ssrn.com/paper=1364273. 38 Padilla, A. Jorge, and Marco Pagano, 2000, Sharing default information as a borrower discipline device, European Economic Review 44, 1951–1980. Pagano, Marco, and Tullio Jappelli, 1993, Information sharing in credit markets, The Journal of Finance 48, 1693–1718. Roy, A. D., 1952, Safety …rst and the holding of assets, Econometrica 20, 431–449. Salas, V., and J. Saurina, 2003, Deregulation, market power and risk behaviour in spanish banks, European Economic Review 47, 1061–1075. Schaeck, Klaus, and Martin Cihak, 2010a, Banking competition and capital ratios, European Financial Management , Forthcoming. , 2010b, Competition, e¢ ciency, and soundness in banking: An industrial organization perspective, European Banking Center Discussion Paper No. 2010-20S, http://ssrn.com/paper=1635245. , and Simon Wolfe, 2009, Are competitive banking systems more stable?, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41, 711–734. Turk Ariss, Rima, 2010, On the implications of market power in banking: Evidence from developing countries, Journal of Banking and Finance 34, 765–775. Vercammen, James A., 1995, Credit bureau policy and sustainable reputation e¤ects in credit markets, Economica 62, 461–478. Wagner, W., 2010, Loan market competition and bank risk-taking, Journal of Financial Services Research 37, 71–81. 39 Table 1: Bank-speci…c variables: Summary Statistics This table shows the total sample summary statistics for the bank speci…c variables used throughout the paper. Bank speci…c data is retrieved from the Bureau Van Dijck Bankscope database. The full sample contains 99963 observations. The table consists of three parts. Panel A contains information on the mean and standard deviation of the variables that are used as control variables in the competition - stability regressions. The impact of banks’ business model on bank soundness is proxied via its funding structure (share of wholesale funding equals the share of money market funding in money market funding and total deposits), asset mix (loans to total assets) and revenue composition (non-interest income in total income). We also control for bank size, credit risk (loan loss provisions to total interest income) and bank strategy (annual growth in total assets). We have three types of banks in our sample: Commercial Banks, Cooperative Banks and Savings Banks. Panel B summarizes the variables that are needed to construct the Lerner index. The Lerner index is the relative markup of price over marginal cost. The average price of bank activities equals the ratio of total revenues over total assets. Marginal costs are obtained after estimating a translog cost function. Using a translog speci…cation, we relate banks’ total operating cost to three input prices (price of …xed assets, price of labor and price of funding). They are constructed as respectively the share of other operating and administrative expenses to total assets, the ratio of personnel expenses to total assets and the ratio of interest expenses to total deposits and money market funding. Panel C contains info on the main variables of interest: market power and bank riskiness. Market power is measured through the Lerner index, whereas our bank stability indicator is the natural logarithm of the Z-score. The Z-score is calculated as the sum of equity over total assets and return on assets divided by the three year rolling standard deviation of return on assets. Variable Mean Standard Deviation Determinants of Bank Soundness Share of Wholesale Funding 0.0417 0.0933 Loans to Total Assets 0.596 0.1795 Non-Interest Revenue Share 0.2256 0.1637 ln(Total Assets) 5.8664 1.8034 Loan Loss Provisions to Interest Income 0.1135 0.1742 Annual Growth in Total Assets 0.0658 0.1804 Commercial Bank dummy 0.6785 0.4671 Cooperative Bank dummy 0.1665 0.3725 Savings Bank dummy 0.155 0.3619 Translog Cost Function Total Operating Cost 166.8183 613.047 Price of Fixed Assets 1.545 2.9279 Price of Labor 0.016 0.0093 Price of Funding 0.0365 0.0335 Average Price of bank activities 0.0752 0.0445 Marginal Cost 0.0639 0.0394 Market Power and Bank Soundness ln(Z-score) 4.0842 1.1529 Lerner 0.1484 0.1419 40 41 Boone -H-statistic HHI(TA) - nbanks Market Share Variables Lerner Bank Soundness 0.409 (0.000) -0.362 (0.000) -0.158 (0.000) 0.029 (0.467) 0.049 (0.226) 0.079 (0.049) Lerner -0.076 (0.038) 0.025 (0.539) 0.110 (0.003) 0.037 (0.313) 0.018 (0.619) 1.000 Market Share 0.401 (0.000) 0.466 (0.000) 0.048 (0.191) -0.023 (0.537) 1.000 - nbanks 0.273 (0.000) -0.053 (0.193) -0.070 (0.087) 1.000 0.112 (0.002) 0.011 (0.770) 1.000 HHI(TA) This table provides information on the correlation between bank soundness and various proxies of bank market power, market structure and competition. Correlation measures are obtained at the time-varying country level. If a variable varies at a more detailed level (e.g. bank soundness varies at the bank level) it is …rst averaged at the time-country level. Bank soundness is the natural logarithm of the Z-score. The Lerner index is a bank-speci…c, time–varying measure of market power. Market Share is the average market share of a bank in a country in a given year. Nbanks is the number of banks in a country. In this table, we use the inverse of the number of banks, such that a higher value indicates an increase in market power. HHI(TA) is the Hirschmann-Her…ndahl index of concentration of total assets. The more disperse the market structure, the lower this value will be. The last two measures are estimated structural competition measures. The estimations are done at the country level over …ve year rolling windows. We take the opposite of the Panzar-Rosse H-statistics, such that a higher value also indicates an increase in market power. Finally, the Boone indicator is a new measure of competition following Boone (2008). All competition or market structure measures are thus constructed that an increase indicates more market power or concentration. p-values are in parentheses. Table 2: Bank Soundness and Competition measures: Correlations 0.152 (0.000) 1.000 -H-statistic Table 3: The market power-bank soundness relationship: Full sample regressions This table contains information on the relationship between competition and stability in the total sample. The total sample consists of 61 countries and spans the time period 1994-2006. Bank soundness (ln Z-score) is the dependent variable and is regressed on a competition proxy (Lerner index), a group of bank speci…c control variables (including specialization dummies) and GDP per capita. We employ the panel structure of the database and control for …xed heterogeneity at the country and time level by including country and time …xed e¤ects. The standard errors are robust and clustered at the bank level. To mitigate the impact of reverse causality, we use one period lagged values of the independent variables. The …rst two columns show OLS estimates, whereas the third column are IV (2SLS) regression results. In the …rst column, we include year and country …xed e¤ects. In the second column, we interact them to account for time-varying country speci…c heterogeneity. In the third column, we take into account that market power may be endogenous. The instruments are loan growth and lagged values of the Lerner index. The Stock-Yogo weak ID test critical values at the 15 per cent level is 11.59 and at the 10 per cent level is 19.93. To avoid that our results are driven by countries that are overrepresented in our sample, we weigh each observation with the inverse of the number of banks in the country. Doing so, we give equal weight to each country. VARIABLES Lerner index Share of Wholesale Funding Loans to Total Assets Non-Interest Revenue Share ln(Total Assets) Loan Loss Provisions to Interest Income Annual Growth in Total Assets GDP per Capita Constant Observations R-squared Type dummies Year dummies Country dummies Time x Country dummies Nr Countries Instruments F-stat_IV J-stat p-value OLS ln(Z-score) OLS ln(Z-score) IV ln(Z-score) 0.957*** (0.0909) -0.0442 (0.111) 0.241*** (0.0845) -0.620*** (0.0893) 0.0230*** (0.00891) -0.595*** (0.0608) -0.287*** (0.0514) -2.23e-05* (1.25e-05) 3.339*** (0.155) 0.931*** (0.0942) -0.0672 (0.117) 0.143* (0.0837) -0.608*** (0.0918) 0.0198** (0.00920) -0.513*** (0.0618) -0.363*** (0.0578) 2.141*** (0.168) 0.0534 (0.121) 0.181** (0.0890) -0.680*** (0.0962) 0.000349 (0.00966) -0.271*** (0.0731) -0.305*** (0.0540) -2.93e-05** (1.28e-05) 3.419*** (0.163) 99963 0.285 YES YES YES NO 61 99963 0.352 YES 2.891*** (0.203) 99115 0.264 YES YES YES YES NO 61 61 lagged Lerner and Loan Growth 630.5 1.128 0.288 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 42 Table 4: Determinants of heterogeneity in the Competition-Stability relationship: summary statistics This table shows the summary statistics for the country-speci…c variables used in this paper. We categorize them in four groups. First, we construct two herding measures: revenue heterogeneity (the within country dispersion of non-interest income share) and systemic risk (measured by the country-level Z-score). The second group is a set of market structure variables: an activity restrictions indicator (higher values indicate more restrictions on activities related to insurance, real estate, underwriting, brokerage), the Hirschmann Her…ndahl index of concentration in total assets and a measure of restrictions on bank entry. The third set of variables is related to regulation and supervision with proxies for the strength of capital regulation, deposit insurance, the number of supervisors and the strength of external governance. The last group of variables captures the …nancial structure of a country and are related to the availability of credit history information, the strength of contract enforcement, GDP per capita and the deepness of the stock market (turnover ratio). Not all variables are available for all countries or for the full sample period (1994-2006). This explains why the number of observations ranges between 524 and 740. Detailed information on the construction and data source of these country-speci…c variables are provided in table13. Observations Mean St. Dev. Herding Heterogeneity - Revenues 740 0.187 0.059 Systemic Stability 616 4.219 0.953 Market Structure Activitity Restrictions 638 9.318 2.339 HHI(Total Assets) 740 1304.967 732.734 Entry Applications Denied 524 0.106 0.201 Regulation and Supervision Strength of Capital Regulation 638 5.904 1.822 ln(DI coverage - GDP per capita) 580 0.799 0.999 Multiple Supervisors 628 0.178 0.383 External Governance 628 12.980 2.020 Institutional and Financial development Credit Registry 740 0.404 0.491 Credit Bureau - Depth 671 4.083 1.818 Contract enforcement - Cost 688 26.972 17.541 GDP per Capita 737 11715.333 12009.704 Stock Market Turnover Ratio 702 0.555 0.623 43 Min Max 0.000 1.178 0.342 6.688 4.000 114.774 0.000 15.000 6903.013 1.000 2.000 -1.347 0.000 6.000 10.000 2.533 1.000 16.800 0.000 0.000 0.000 281.620 0.003 1.000 6.000 122.700 54629.023 6.224 Table 5: Determinants of heterogeneity in the Competition-Stability relationship: binary classi…cation results The …rst column of the table reports the country-speci…c characteristics that are hypothesized to in‡uence the competition-stability relationship. For each of these characteristics, we divide our sample countries in a high and a low group, indicating whether the value of this characteristic for a speci…c country is above (high) or below (low) the median over the sample of countries. The …rst group consists of two herding measures: revenue heterogeneity (within-country dispersion of banks’ non-interest income share) and systemic stability. The second group is a set of market structure variables: an activity restrictions indicator (higher values indicate more restrictions on activities related to insurance, real estate, underwriting, brokerage), the Hirschmann Her…ndahl index of concentration in total assets and a measure of restrictions on bank entry. The third set of variables is related to regulation and supervision with proxies for the strength of capital regulation, deposit insurance, the number of supervisors and the strength of external governance. The last group of variables captures the …nancial structure of a country and are related to the availability of credit history information, the strength of credit enforcement, GDP per capita and the deepness of the stock market (turnover ratio). The table consists of two panels and each panel consists of two sets of columns. The …rst panel contains the results for the separate approach. In the separate approach, we …rst compute a measure of the strength of the market power-stability relationship for each country. Subsequently, we test whether the average is di¤erent in the high or low group. The left hand side part contains info on the test of di¤erences in the pairwise correlation coe¢ cient (unconditional correlation), whereas the right hand side part tests for di¤erences in the average of the estimated coe¢ cients on the Lerner index (in a country-speci…c regression of bank stability on competition and a group of control variables). For each country-speci…c characteristic, we report the number of countries in each group, the average value in each group as well as the p-value of the t-test of equal means (allowing for unequal variances). The second panel contains the results for the pooled approach. In the pooled approach, we regress our stability measure (Z-score) on the Lerner index and a group of control variables for the total sample. We interact each explanatory variable with a dummy indicating whether the bank belongs to a country from the high or to the low group (based on the country-speci…c characteristic under investigation). The left hand side panel shows the OLS results, whereas the right hand side panel shows IV (2SLS) results, where we use loan growth and lags of the Lerner index to instrument our competition measure in these regressions. To avoid that the results in the pooled approach are driven by countries that are overrepresented in our sample, we weigh each observation with the inverse of the number of banks in the country. Doing so, we give equal weight to each country. For each country-speci…c characteristic, we report the estimated beta coe¢ cient of the Lerner index in the low and high group as well as the p-value of the Chow test, which indicates whether the average conditional correlation coe¢ cient between competition and stability is di¤erent across both groups. All pooled regressions include time varying country …xed e¤ects and specialization dummies. The separate regressions include year and specialization dummies. 44 Panel A: Separate Approach Heterogeneity - Revenues Systemic Stability Activitity Restrictions HHI(Total Assets) Entry Applications Denied Strength of Capital Regulation DI coverage - GDP per capita Multiple Supervisors External Governance Credit Registry Credit Bureau - Depth Contract enforcement - Cost GDP per Capita Stock Market Turnover Ratio Unconditional Number of Countries Average p-value Herding Low 31 0.269 0.003 High 31 0.152 Low 31 0.219 0.358 High 31 0.203 Market Structure Low 30 0.164 0.006 High 28 0.275 Low 31 0.251 0.032 High 31 0.170 Low 27 0.195 0.104 High 26 0.254 Regulation and Supervision Low 29 0.236 0.216 High 29 0.200 Low 26 0.143 0.008 High 26 0.257 Low 39 0.194 0.048 High 19 0.267 Low 29 0.225 0.377 High 29 0.211 Institutional and Financial Development Low 36 0.202 0.327 High 26 0.222 Low 28 0.218 0.307 High 27 0.197 Low 29 0.218 0.277 High 28 0.193 Low 31 0.212 0.359 High 30 0.197 Low 31 0.151 0.003 High 30 0.271 45 Conditional Average p-value 1.271 0.872 1.088 1.055 0.104 0.872 1.487 1.218 0.925 0.909 1.519 0.021 1.249 1.088 0.629 1.453 1.081 1.348 1.400 0.938 0.302 1.005 1.164 1.202 1.061 1.318 0.919 1.026 1.146 0.648 1.535 0.305 0.458 0.178 0.031 0.011 0.196 0.067 0.335 0.112 0.355 0.002 Panel B: Pooled Approach OLS Number of Countries Beta p-value Herding Heterogeneity - Revenues Low 31 1.226 0.001 High 31 0.622 Systemic Stability Low 31 0.816 0.168 High 31 1.081 Market Structure Activitity Restrictions Low 30 0.754 0.020 High 28 1.221 HHI(Total Assets) Low 31 1.138 0.023 High 31 0.710 Entry Applications Denied Low 27 0.963 0.261 High 26 1.209 Regulation and Supervision Strength of Capital Regulation Low 29 0.992 0.848 High 29 1.030 DI coverage - GDP per capita Low 26 0.722 0.036 High 26 1.144 Multiple Supervisors Low 39 1.033 0.737 High 19 0.964 External Governance Low 29 1.127 0.208 High 29 0.877 Institutional and Financial Development Credit Registry Low 36 0.931 0.861 High 26 0.964 Credit Bureau - Depth Low 28 0.934 0.987 High 27 0.931 Contract enforcement - Cost Low 29 1.023 0.362 High 28 0.845 GDP per Capita Low 31 0.911 0.364 High 30 1.093 Stock Market Turnover Ratio Low 31 0.616 0.000 High 30 1.442 46 IV(2SLS) Beta (IV) p-value 2.570 1.770 2.241 2.060 0.021 1.918 2.652 2.874 1.540 2.187 2.945 0.042 2.404 2.231 1.514 2.595 1.949 3.300 2.322 2.340 0.634 2.470 1.857 2.546 1.906 2.693 1.692 2.054 2.545 1.498 3.204 0.071 0.594 0.000 0.050 0.003 0.001 0.961 0.064 0.004 0.165 0.000 47 Stock Market Turnover Ratio Multiple Supervisors DI coverage - GDP per capita Entry Applications Denied HHI(Total Assets) Activitity Restrictions Heterogeneity - Revenues Lerner Variables Conditional Correlation Unconditional correlations 0.719 (0.000) -0.183 (0.154) -0.337 (0.007) 0.298 (0.023) -0.275 (0.031) 0.239 (0.071) 0.361 (0.009) 0.243 (0.066) 0.290 (0.023) Conditional Correlation 0.003 (0.982) -0.218 (0.088) 0.293 (0.025) -0.191 (0.136) 0.327 (0.012) 0.314 (0.023) 0.108 (0.419) 0.163 (0.210) 1.000 Lerner -0.155 (0.229) -0.271 (0.039) 0.245 (0.054) -0.128 (0.338) -0.310 (0.026) -0.020 (0.879) 0.012 (0.924) 1.000 Heterogeneity - Revenues -0.264 (0.045) 0.223 (0.082) -0.130 (0.331) -0.189 (0.180) -0.040 (0.765) 0.055 (0.676) 1.000 Activitity Restrictions -0.062 (0.645) 0.253 (0.056) 0.534 (0.000) 0.014 (0.916) -0.050 (0.707) 1.000 HHI(Total Assets) -0.010 (0.943) -0.050 (0.726) -0.204 (0.124) -0.132 (0.312) 1.000 Entry Applications Denied 0.440 (0.002) 0.010 (0.942) 0.136 (0.310) 1.000 0.129 (0.382) 0.145 (0.309) 1.000 DI coverage - GDP per capita This table provides information on the correlation between the market power-stability relationship and a selection of country-speci…c variables. The table contains pairwise correlation coe¢ cients as well as p-values (in brackets) that indicate the signi…cance of the correlation. The market power-stability relationship is proxied by both the unconditional (pairwise) correlation and the conditional (regression-based) correlation. The country-speci…c variables are a subset of the full set of country-speci…c characteristics. The selection of the variables is based on signi…cance in the binary (low/high groups) classi…cation approach (either separate or pooled). This binary approach shows that these characteristics potentially play an important role in the competition-stability relationship. The correlation table con…rms these …ndings and also provides information on how these country-speci…c variables are correlated with each other. Table 6: Determinants of heterogeneity in the Competition-Stability relationship: correlation table 0.374 (0.004) 1.000 Multiple Supervisors 48 Observations R-squared Control Variables Type dummies Year x Country dummies Nr Countries 97593 0.341 YES YES YES 51 2.851*** (0.202) 0.964*** (0.109) -0.268*** (0.0940) Lerner index Heterogeneity - Revenues x Lerner Activity Restrictions x Lerner HHI of Total Assets x Lerner Entry Applications denied x Lerner DI coverage - GDP per capita x Lerner Multiple Supervisors x Lerner Stock Market Turnover Ratio x Lerner Constant ln(Zscore) VARIABLES 96543 0.353 YES YES YES 47 2.789*** (0.203) 0.205** (0.0878) 1.035*** (0.116) ln(Zscore) 2.817*** (0.210) -0.0613 (0.127) 1.031*** (0.129) ln(Zscore) 2.797*** (0.202) 0.195** (0.0829) 0.964*** (0.110) ln(Zscore) 96434 0.350 YES YES YES 47 2.840*** (0.203) 0.121 (0.0857) 1.051*** (0.116) ln(Zscore) 97593 94695 97593 0.341 0.362 0.340 YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES 51 45 51 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 2.767*** (0.202) -0.316*** (0.122) 0.958*** (0.116) ln(Zscore) 97593 0.340 YES YES YES 51 0.152** (0.0732) 2.816*** (0.202) 1.012*** (0.109) ln(Zscore) 96543 0.357 YES YES YES 47 0.171** (0.0763) 2.839*** (0.203) 0.115 (0.122) 1.026*** (0.125) -0.446*** (0.0944) 0.106 (0.111) -0.241* (0.143) ln(Zscore) 96543 0.363 YES YES YES 47 0.157* (0.0863) 2.841*** (0.206) 0.974*** (0.128) -0.408*** (0.0968) 0.137 (0.0957) -0.321** (0.136) ln(Zscore) 97593 0.343 YES YES YES 51 0.155** (0.0741) 2.838*** (0.202) 0.137* (0.0817) -0.219* (0.121) 0.931*** (0.115) -0.269*** (0.0941) ln(Zscore) This table contains information on the drivers of the relationship between competition and stability in the total sample. The regressions are based on the baseline regression at the bank level (see table 3), i.e. when regressing our stability measure (Z-score) on the Lerner index and a group of bank-speci…c control variables.We employ the panel structure of the database and control for …xed heterogeneity at the year-country level by interacting country and time …xed e¤ects. We also add banktype dummies to the regression. Furthermore, to mitigate the impact of reverse causality, we use one period lagged values of the independent variables. To avoid that our results are driven by countries that are overrepresented in our sample, we weigh each variable with the inverse of the number of banks in the country. Doing so, we give equal weight to each country. The standard errors are robust and clustered at the bank level. In the …rst seven columns, we add an interaction term of the Lerner index with a country-speci…c characteristic to the basic regression. Doing so, we present a continuous extension to the binary approaches in the separate and pooled analysis. The choice of interaction variables is guided by signi…cance in the previous part of the analysis. The continuous approach exploits all of the variation in the country-speci…c variables. In the last three columns, we show the result when we add multiple interaction terms simultaneously (that are individually signi…cant). For ease of comparability (in terms of economic signi…cance), all country-speci…c variables have been normalized to have zero mean and unit variance. Table 7: Determinants of heterogeneity in the Competition-Stability relationship: regression results Table 8: Drivers of Time-varying Conditional Correlation between Lerner and Z-score This table explains the variation in the conditional (regression-based), time-varying correlation between bank stability and competition by regressing these correlation coe¢ cients on country-speci…c characteristics. The time-varying correlation is retrieved by running country by country regressions over …ve year rolling windows. More speci…cally, for each country we regress our bank stability measure (Z-score) on the Lerner index, a group of bank-speci…c control variables and GDP per capita, while using …ve year rolling windows. Since our sample period is 1994-2006, and taking into account that we lag our independent variables with one period, we get a maximum of eight countryspeci…c conditional correlations. The retrieved conditional correlation is subsequently matched to country-speci…c variables measured at the …rst year of the …ve year window. As our dependent variable is an estimated dependent variable, we require at least 30 observations over the …ve year estimation period. All three regressions also include year-speci…c e¤ects. VARIABLES Heterogeneity - Revenues HHI of Total Assets DI coverage - GDP per capita Stock Market Turnover Ratio Activity Restrictions Multiple Supervisors Entry Applications Denied Constant -0.0524 (0.0863) -0.0379 (0.115) 0.453*** (0.116) 0.210* (0.0969) 0.298*** (0.0452) 0.0729 (0.0784) 0.0544 (0.0350) 1.358*** (0.0441) -0.276** (0.104) -0.114 (0.102) 0.332** (0.120) 0.175* (0.0879) 0.182** (0.0642) -0.316** (0.101) -0.135 (0.0840) 0.378*** (0.0795) 0.162* (0.0785) 0.939*** (0.0294) 0.918*** (0.0209) Observations 257 303 R-squared 0.244 0.163 Year dummies YES YES clustered standard errors TIME TIME Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 49 326 0.143 YES TIME 50 Observations R-squared Type dummies Time x Country dummies Constant Annual Growth in Total Assets 0.931*** (0.0942) -0.0672 (0.117) 0.143* (0.0837) -0.608*** (0.0918) 0.0198** (0.00920) -0.513*** (0.0618) -0.363*** (0.0578) 2.891*** (0.203) (1) ln(Z-score) 0.0433*** (0.00218) 0.00169 (0.00264) -0.00245 (0.00156) -7.14e-05 (0.00196) -0.000670*** (0.000166) 0.00319** (0.00150) 0.00358*** (0.00135) 0.0182*** (0.00507) (2) ROA 99963 0.379 YES YES 0.0618*** (0.0109) 0.0315** (0.0133) -0.0622*** (0.00964) -0.0148 (0.0109) -0.0238*** (0.00102) 0.00239 (0.00481) -0.0482*** (0.00593) 0.341*** (0.0180) (3) Equity/TA 99963 99963 0.352 0.306 YES YES YES YES Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Loan Loss Provisions to Interest Income ln(Total Assets) Non-Interest Revenue Share Loans to Total Assets Share of Wholesale Funding Lerner index VARIABLES 99963 0.406 YES YES -0.483*** (0.0670) 0.185* (0.0946) -0.241*** (0.0532) 0.265*** (0.0583) -0.0957*** (0.00586) 0.302*** (0.0405) 0.0760* (0.0418) 1.803*** (0.204) (4) (ROA) 99286 0.272 YES YES 0.00995 (0.0140) -0.196*** (0.0432) -0.241*** (0.0198) -0.0314 (0.0286) 0.204*** (0.0205) 0.120*** (0.0263) 0.00847*** (0.00183) (5) NPL This table shows the results for the total sample competition-stability regressions. The …rst column shows the standard results when using the Z-score as stability measure and regressing it on the Lerner index and a group of bank-speci…c control variables. For regression (2) to (5) we use four alternative stability measures, being nonperforming loans and the three subcomponents of the Z-score (equity over total assets, return on assets and the three year volatility of the return on assets). For each stability measure we perform the basic regression with country-year …xed e¤ects. When using non-performing loans as stability measure, we leave out the loan loss provisions over interest income ratio as a control variable, since both variables are heavily related to each other. Table 9: Alternative risk measures Table 10: Failing Banks This table shows regression results for the competition-stability trade-o¤ while checking for the impact of failing banks. The …rst column shows our baseline regression for the full sample. We regress the Z-score on the Lerner index and a group of bank-speci…c control variables, country-year dummies and bank type dummies. In the second and the third regression, we interact the Lerner index with an exit dummy. For the second regression, the exit dummy equals one in the two years before the bank leaves the sample. Notice that this dummy does not discrimate between defaults and distressed mergers on the one hand and ’normal’ mergers or acquisitions on the other hand. Therefore, in the third regression, the exit dummy only equals one in the two years before a bank leaves the sample and the bank had a negative ROA in that period. In this way, we only capture the banks that actually where in distress before they leave the sample. The signi…cant and positive interaction term between competition and the distressed exit dummy indicates that these banks that are in trouble before leaving the sample react more strongly to a change in competition. Thus, banks that are in distress gamble even more than others when competition rises, probably because there is not much left to loose for them. In the fourth regression, we only look at banks that did not exit the sample Exit Dummy =0). We use these banks to redo our continuous analysis, where we regress the Z-score on the Lerner index, a group of control variables and on interaction terms between the Lerner index and country-speci…c characteristics. For each regression, error terms are clustered at the bank level. Lerner index Baseline Exit Distressed Exit Not Distressed 0.931*** (0.0942) 0.977*** (0.0996) -0.254 (0.156) 0.878*** (0.0985) 0.914*** (0.117) Lerner x Exit Lerner x Distressed Exit Heterogeneity - Revenues x Lerner HHI of Total Assets x Lerner DI coverage - GDP per capita x Lerner Stock Market Turnover Ratio x Lerner Constant 0.617** (0.271) 2.891*** (0.203) 2.885*** (0.203) 2.908*** (0.203) Observations 99,963 99,963 99,963 R-squared 0.352 0.352 0.352 Control Variables YES YES YES Type dummies YES YES YES Year x Country dummies YES YES YES Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 51 -0.292*** (0.0857) -0.202 (0.126) 0.183** (0.0845) 0.117 (0.0772) 2.810*** (0.203) 96836 0.337 YES YES YES 52 Observations R-squared Control Variables Type dummies Year x Country dummies Heterogeneity - Revenues x Lerner HHI of Total Assets x Lerner DI coverage - GDP per capita x Lerner Stock Market Turnover Ratio x Lerner Constant Lerner x Lerner TBTF(25%) x Lerner TBTF x Lerner Large Market Share x Lerner Market Share x Lerner Lerner index 99963 0.352 YES YES YES 2.891*** (0.203) 0.931*** (0.0942) Baseline 99963 0.352 YES YES YES 2.914*** (0.205) 0.912*** (0.0952) 0.278 (0.219) Market Share 2.929*** (0.206) 0.682 (0.560) 0.917*** (0.0941) Too Big to Fail 99963 99963 0.352 0.352 YES YES YES YES YES YES Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 2.886*** (0.205) -0.384 (1.312) 0.941*** (0.0967) Large Market Share 99963 0.352 YES YES YES 2.930*** (0.204) 0.574* (0.313) 0.923*** (0.0941) Too Big to Fail 25% 99963 0.352 YES YES YES 2.872*** (0.204) 0.0459 (0.0493) 0.953*** (0.0987) Lerner-squared 97593 0.343 YES YES YES 0.0251 (0.0575) -0.329*** (0.0804) -0.220* (0.119) 0.156* (0.0863) 0.145** (0.0734) 2.820*** (0.203) 0.970*** (0.115) Lerner-squared This table shows the results for the basic stability-competition regression, while controlling for the impact of bank size in various ways. The question here is whether banks with a larger market share have a stronger incentive to take more risk, because they can potentially see themselves as too-big-to-fail. In the …rst column the results for the basic regression are shown, i.e a regression of the Z-score on the Lerner index and a group of bank-speci…c control variables, while also controlling for country-year and bank type e¤ects. In the second column, we add an interaction term between the Lerner index and a bank’s market share (total assets market share). In the third column we introduce a dummy that equals one for banks having a market share larger than 10 percent. We interact this dummy with the Lerner index to see whether these banks react di¤erently to a change in competition. In the fourth and …fth column, we proxy Too-big-to-fail by the ration of bank size to a country’s GDP. We interact the Lerner index with this share (column 4) or a dummy variable that is one if this share exceeds 25Column 6 shows an updated version of the basic competition-stability regression, including a squared Lerner index. Column 7 also adds the interaction terms between the Lerner index and a group of country-speci…c characteristics. By including the squared term, we control for potential non-linear competition e¤ects and reduce the possibility that the other interaction terms are picking up a competition e¤ect. For each regression, error terms are clustered at the bank level. Table 11: Robustness test - Market Share 53 3.300272 3.644814 3.75954 3.568 SLOVAK REPUBLIC INDIA NORWAY Average 0.071 0.121 0.184 0.126 0.136 0.098 0.118 0.117 Lerner 3.047 3.260 3.732 3.346 3.840 3.721 3.936 3.832 ln(Z-score) Rev. Heterogeneity Lowest Vigintile 0.168 0.228 0.238 0.211 Highest vigintile 0.187 0.151 0.133 0.157 1587.153 836.9371 1647.784 1357.291 2671.202 356.2214 1783.815 1603.746 HHI(TA) 0.973 1.526 1.925 1.475 1.463 -0.908 -0.349 0.069 DI coverage This table summarizes country-speci…c characteristics over the full sample period for the 5 percent of countries with the highest and lowest conditional correlation between bank competition and stability. We focus on the characteristics that have a signi…cant impact on this relationship, being bank market concentration (HHI), revenue heterogeneity, deposit insurance and the stock market turnover ratio. This table allows us to check whether our results hold for the countries at both extremes of the competition-stability spectrum. The results in these table con…rm our previous …ndings. Countries where bank market power has a strong positive impact on bank stability tend to have less concentrated banking markets, a lower degree of revenue heterogeneity, more generous deposit insurance and deeper stock markets. -2.6494 -2.00572 -1.5465 -2.067 Cond.corr. VIETNAM LUXEMBOURG IRELAND Average Country Table 12: Economic assessement 0.550 1.600 0.822 0.991 0.194 0.018 0.462 0.225 stock market 10 11 11 10.667 9 7 8 Act. Res. 25 80 130 78.333 31 144 41 72 banks 54 Entry applications denied Doing Business database Doing Business database Financial structure database, Beck and Demirguc-Kunt (2009) World Development Indicators, World Bank GDP per capita Institutional and …nancial development Doing Business database Credit Bureau - Depth Contract Enforcement - cost Stock market turnover ratio Credit Registry External governance Bank regulation and supervision database , Barth et al. (2000,2003,2008) Bank regulation and supervision database , Barth et al. (2000,2003,2008) Regulation and Supervision Bank regulation and supervision database , Barth et al. (2000,2003,2008) Deposit insurance around the world database , Demirguc-Kunt et al. (2005) Bank regulation and supervision database , Barth et al. (2000,2003,2008) Bank concentration Capital regulatory index Deposit Insurance coverage Multiple supervisors Bankscope, own calculations Activity restrictions Herding Bankscope, own calculations Source Bankscope, own calculations Market structure Bank regulation and supervision database , Barth et al. (2000,2003,2008) Systemic Stability Revenue Heterogeneity Variable Table 13: Country-speci…c characteristics Dummy capturing whether there is a private and/or public credit registry Strength of the information content of the credit bureaus This variable measures the cost of enforcing a contract Ratio of the value of total shares traded to average real market capitalization Gross Domestic Product per capita The strength of capital regulation in a country Deposit insurance coverage relative to GDP per capita Dummy equal to one when there are multiple bank supervisors The strength of external auditors, …nancial statement transparancy, and the existence of an external rating Degree to which banks can participate in various non-interest income activities. Measured as the Hirschmann-Her…ndahl index (HHI) of total assets % of entry applications that were denied Within country standard deviation of non-interest income share Z-score at the country level Description 55 Country ARGENTINA AUSTRIA AUSTRALIA BANGLADESH BELGIUM BRAZIL CANADA SWITZERLAND CHILE COLOMBIA COSTA RICA CYPRUS CZECH REPUBLIC GERMANY DENMARK DOMINICAN REPUBLIC ECUADOR SPAIN FRANCE UNITED KINGDOM GREECE HONG KONG, CHINA CROATIA HUNGARY INDONESIA IRELAND INDIA ITALY JAPAN KENYA ln(Z-score) 2.755 3.963 3.997 3.235 3.723 2.852 3.791 4.596 3.551 2.715 3.851 2.462 3.014 4.543 3.752 3.267 3.273 4.287 3.910 3.839 3.044 3.924 3.357 3.267 3.138 3.936 3.260 4.064 3.429 3.619 Lerner 0.050 0.108 0.146 0.164 0.082 0.128 0.108 0.167 0.152 0.015 0.093 0.073 0.096 0.083 0.220 -0.004 0.105 0.168 0.099 0.128 0.140 0.164 0.097 0.110 0.078 0.118 0.121 0.155 0.003 0.172 GDP per cap. 7568.866 23998.51 20717.88 364.1659 21897.4 3714.598 22823.11 34157.36 4879.885 2451.793 4251.311 12410.36 5657.648 22530.21 29218.36 2175.146 1428.235 14133.81 21842.6 24521.81 11793.78 25376.1 4261.193 4904.271 852.8801 25111.98 480.6477 19067.38 37199.11 410.1668 banks 130 278 41 33 86 188 72 524 36 41 57 20 37 2535 110 35 37 245 462 195 29 48 61 38 114 41 80 866 852 42 Country KOREA, REP. KAZAKHSTAN LEBANON LUXEMBOURG LATVIA MEXICO MALAYSIA NIGERIA NETHERLANDS NORWAY PANAMA PERU PHILIPPINES PAKISTAN POLAND PORTUGAL PARAGUAY ROMANIA RUSSIAN FEDERATION SWEDEN SINGAPORE SLOVENIA SLOVAK REPUBLIC THAILAND TURKEY UKRAINE UNITED STATES URUGUAY VENEZUELA, RB VIETNAM SOUTH AFRICA Table 14: Country List ln(Z-score) 2.612 3.201 3.503 3.721 2.639 2.662 3.309 2.923 3.934 3.732 3.559 3.232 3.906 2.956 3.072 3.611 2.860 2.861 3.213 3.840 4.094 3.509 3.047 2.430 2.449 3.131 4.172 2.270 2.780 3.840 3.359 Lerner 0.090 0.137 0.101 0.098 0.136 0.039 0.173 0.190 0.123 0.184 0.157 -0.036 0.104 0.128 0.093 0.089 0.080 0.085 0.107 0.196 0.213 0.118 0.071 0.043 0.128 0.139 0.185 -0.038 0.146 0.136 0.092 GDP per cap. 12095.13 1696.844 4600.541 43511.89 3527.425 5396.252 4013.81 377.1743 23164.49 37589.07 3978.826 2091.894 1001.83 543.7955 4417.057 10412.33 1380.28 2032.468 2208.739 29016.04 23597.53 10923.43 3975.83 2167.972 4013.615 850.3606 35132.82 6031.189 4728.954 466.2205 3110.659 banks 29 26 64 144 30 48 50 75 64 130 95 29 61 29 68 37 26 29 1003 107 21 23 25 26 57 62 10088 51 63 31 39 LURUBDVNUAMXCHIE DKSGDENLPETRSI CRATPABEPYARSEUYBRECLBGBKZVEPLPTRODOAUHUGRIT CAKEZALVCLCYCOFRID IN ESHRPKNGUSKRSKPHHKMYCZJPTHNOTW Figure 1: Pairwise Correlation of Bank Market Power and Stability The graph contains information on the relationship between bank market power and bank soundness. Bank market power is proxied by the Lerner index. Bank soundness is captured by the Z-score, which equals the number of standard deviations bank pro…ts have to fall before the equity cushion s depleted. The full sample correlation is depicted by the black line and equals 0.252. The full sample consists of banks from 62 countries. The set of countries is heterogeneous and they have di¤erent regulatory frameworks and institutional settings. We conjecture that this heterogeneity across countries countries may a¤ect the competition-stability relationship at the country level. This requires that the competition-soundness relationship also exhibits variation at the country level. The height of the bars shows the pairwise correlation between market power and bank soundness per country. The bars are sorted from low to high and the country labels are mentioned on the X-axis. The correlations that are signi…cantly di¤erent from zero have a lighter shade. The average pairwise correlation over the 62 countries ressembles the full sample correlation. However, there is a large amount of heterogeneity in the competition-stability relationship, with correlations ranging from below -0.2 to above 0.5. The standard deviation of the correlation across the 62 countries is 0.173. Pairwise correlation of Bank Market Power and Stability .4 .2 0 -.2 Pairwise Correlation Coefficient .6 Heterogeneity across 62 Countries insignificant significant Red line = Full sample pairwise correlation (=0.252) Country Average=.211, Country Standard Deviation=.173 56 VNLUIE NLMXUAPERUSI PADELBBDDKHUCHTWDOARKZSESGLVBEID ROECTRPYZABRATKRGBPLTHMYHKCRHRPKKEIT VEUYPHCLUSESGRCAJPFRNGCYPTAUCOCZSKIN NO Figure 2: Conditional Correlation of Bank Market Power and Stability The graph contains information on the relationship between bank market power and bank soundness. Bank market power is proxied by the Lerner index. Bank soundness is captured by the Z-score, which equals the number of standard deviations bank pro…ts have to fall before the equity cushion is depleted. The full black line crosses the Yaxis at the value of the estimated coe¢ cient of the Lerner index retrieved by regressing stability on bank soundness and a set of control variables (see Equation (2) ). The dotted lines indicate a 95 percent con…dence interval. We conjecture that this heterogeneity across countries countries may a¤ect the competition-stability relationship at the country level. This requires that the competition-soundness relationship also exhibits variation at the country level. The height of the bars shows the magnitude of the coe¢ cient of the Lerner index when estimating Equation X for each country separately. The bars are sorted from low to high and the country labels are mentioned on the X-axis. The coe¢ cients that are signi…cantly di¤erent from zero have a lighter shade. The average of the 62 estimated coe¢ cients equals 1.07, which ressembles the full sample coe¢ cient. However, there is a large amount of heterogeneity in the competition-stability relationship. The standard deviation of the coe¢ cient across the 62 countries is 1.24. Conditional correlation of Bank Market Power and Stability 2 0 -2 -4 Regression coefficient Lerner 4 Heterogeneity across 62 Countries insignificant significant Red line: full sample beta (=1.011) and 95% confidence bounds Country Average=0.982, Country Standard Deviation=1.464 1 57