Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore CENTRO DI RICERCHE IN ANALISI ECONOMICA E SVILUPPO ECONOMICO INTERNAZIONALE Investing in Knowledge: Knowledge, Human Capital and Institutions for the Long Run Growth Daniele Schilirò ISBN 978-88-343-1790-7 € 3,00 Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore CENTRO DI RICERCHE IN ANALISI ECONOMICA E SVILUPPO ECONOMICO INTERNAZIONALE Investing in Knowledge: Knowledge, Human Capital and Institutions for the Long Run Growth Daniele Schilirò Novembre 2008 Daniele Schilirò, Dipartimento DESMAS ‘Vilfredo Pareto’, Università degli Studi di Messina, [email protected] [email protected] www.vitaepensiero.it All rights reserved. Photocopies for personal use of the reader, not exceeding 15% of each volume, may be made under the payment of a copying fee to the SIAE, in accordance with the provisions of the law n. 633 of 22 april 1941 (art. 68, par. 4 and 5). Reproductions which are not intended for personal use may be only made with the written permission of AIDRO, Corso di Porta Romana n. 108, 20122 Milano, e-mail: [email protected], web site www.aidro.org Le fotocopie per uso personale del lettore possono essere effettuate nei limiti del 15% di ciascun volume dietro pagamento alla SIAE del compenso previsto dall’art. 68, commi 4 e 5, della legge 22 aprile 1941 n. 633. Le riproduzioni effettuate per finalità di carattere professionale, economico o commerciale o comunque per uso diverso da quello personale possono essere effettuate a seguito di specifica autorizzazione rilasciata da AIDRO, Corso di Porta Romana n. 108, 20122 Milano, e-mail: [email protected] e sito web www.aidro.org © 2008 Daniele Schilirò ISBN 978-88-343-1790-7 Abstract The essay aims at arguing that investing in knowledge is one of the main cause of the deep transformations in the structure of modern economies and also a strategic engine for the long run growth. In the recent years a clear long-standing trend in the OECD area have emerged, which is reflected in the expansion of knowledge-related investments and activities, thus transforming the industrial economies into knowledge-based economies. This paper, which is sympathetic with a Schumpeterian view that looks at the modern economic growth as a knowledge-driven process, shows that long run growth is a complex process that cannot be explained by one factor alone. Whereas in the Schumpeterian economy technological progress is the driver of economic growth, so goods are produced under conditions of substantial increasing returns to scale, and innovation becomes the principle source of wealth, in this work the former view is enriched with the idea that institutions have an important role to play in the creation and diffusion of new knowledge and in the process of growth, even if it is difficult to establish ex ante the nature of these relations. The topics of the paper concern scientific and technological knowledge and its relationship with human capital, the issue of open science and the necessary setting of appropriate institutions for knowledge creation. Moreover, an examination of OECD data related to investment in knowledge in OECD countries, with particular attention to human capital, is carried out to evaluate their economic performances. In such a context, the need of a long term growth policy for the EU economies consistent with the Lisbon Agenda is set forth; therefore the paper tries to suggest some proposals for a long term growth policy of the EU economies in this direction. Finally, conclusions end up the paper. 3 Abstract Il saggio vuole dimostrare con una serie di argomentazioni teoriche e con il supporto di alcuni dati OCSE che l’ investire in conoscenza è una delle cause principali delle profonde trasformazioni nella struttura delle economie moderne ed anche un motore formidabile per la crescita di lungo periodo. Negli anni recenti si è registrato un chiaro trend nell’area dei paesi OCSE, riflesso nell’espansione degli investimenti e attività collegate alla conoscenza, che ha trasformato le economie industriali in economie basate sella conoscenza. Questo lavoro, in sintonia con quella visone Schumpeteriana che guarda alla moderna crescita economica come un processo governato dalla conoscenza, mostra che la crescita di lungo periodo è in realtà un processo assai complesso che non può certamente essere spiegato da un unico fattore. In questo lavoro la visione Schumpeteriana basata sul progresso tecnologico che costituisce l’elemento motore della crescita economica, e sull’innovazione che diventa la principale fonte di ricchezza, viene arricchita con l’idea che le istituzioni hanno un ruolo importante da svolgere nella creazione e diffusione di nuove conoscenze e nel processo di crescita, anche se è difficile stabilire ex ante la natura di queste relazioni. Gli argomenti affrontati nel saggio riguardano la conoscenza scientifica e tecnologica e la sua relazione con il capitale umano, la questione della scienza come sistema aperto e la necessaria messa a punto di istituzioni appropriate per la creazione di nuova conoscenza. Inoltre,viene svolta un’analisi dei dati OCSE relativi all’investimento in conoscenza nei paesi OCSE, con particolare riguardo al capitale umano, per valutare la loro performance economica. Inoltre, è posta in evidenza la necessità di una politica per la crescita di lungo periodo per le economie dei Paesi dell’Unione Europea coerente con la strategia di Lisbona, il saggio cerca quindi di suggerire alcune proposte di policy per la crescita di lungo periodo dell’economie dell’Unione Europea che vanno nella direzione dell’Agenda di Lisbona. 4 Index Introduction 7 1. Knowledge and Human Capital 9 2. Institutions matter: the issue of ‘open knowledge’ 16 3. Investing in knowledge: performances and policies for the growth 19 Conclusions 27 References 29 Working Paper Series 32 5 Introduction* An increasing economic literature suggests that the ability to create, distribute and exploit knowledge is central to competitive advantage, wealth creation and better standards of living. Investing in knowledge becomes the ideal strategy to increase the productive capacity of capital goods, labour and natural resource inputs, and it is considered one of the main cause of the deep transformations in the structure of modern economies and also a strategic engine for the long run growth. Joel Mokyr (2002, 2005a) maintains that the central fact of modern economic growth is the irreversibility of the accumulation of useful knowledge paired to ever falling access costs, so that useful knowledge can be disseminated to all those who can use it for production. He also thinks that necessary changes in the institutions to complement technological progress are required, since intellectual factors never operate alone, hence institutional changes become equally important. In the recent years it appears clear the existence of a longstanding trend in the OECD area, reflected in the expansion of knowledge-related investments and activities, transforming the industrial economies into knowledge-based economies. The term ‘knowledge-based economy’ reveals a “sea-change” from the past and it captures a qualitative distinction in the organization and production of the economic system. This concept indicates that the content and structure of economic activities, as well as many social foundations of industrialized countries, may be distinguished from their historical antecedents by the rate and extent of knowledge generation and use (Steinmueller, 2002). One of the * This essay belongs to the research project “Dinamica strutturale: profili storici, tecnologici e organizzativo-istituzionali”. This project is supported by Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, linea D.1 anno 2006, under the direction of professor Alberto Quadrio Curzio at CRANEC. An earlier draft of the paper has been presented at the Workshop “New Forms of Division of Labour, Innovation and Local Development” University of Salento, Lecce, 26-27 January 2007. I wish to thank Nicola De Liso for his helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. 7 main feature of knowledge-based economies is their reliance on new information technologies. The rapid development of scientific and technological knowledge base and the high level of innovation also mark the knowledge-based economies: these are actually the main factors that foster economic growth. In such economies, moreover, the share of intangible capital is greater than that of tangible capital in the overall stock of real capital, and the proportion of knowledgeintensive jobs is high, so the endowment and the quality of human capital become also crucial for the growth. Finally, in the knowledge-based economies the weight of service activities tends to increase, whereas the manufacturing sector changes its structure of production and its organization. This view is supported by the evolutionary economists (Foray and Lundvall, 1996; Abramowitz and David, 1996; OECD, 1996; Steinmueller, 2002; Mokyr, 2002; David and Foray, 2003; Foray, 2004), for whom the emergence of a knowledge-based economy is invoked as a factor to explain historical developments and structural economic changes. Evolutionary economists, we know, are fascinated with non-equilibrium dynamics of co-evolutions over time, whereas neoclassical economists emphasizes the continuous operation of the equilibrium-seeking market mechanism as a problem-solver at each moment of time. In this paper I am sympathetic with a Schumpeterian view that looks at the modern economic growth as a knowledge-driven process. Although I am aware that long run growth is a complex process that cannot be explained by one factor alone. Essentially in the Schumpeterian economy technological progress is the driver of economic growth, so goods are produced under conditions of substantial increasing returns to scale, and innovation becomes the principle source of wealth. This view must be enriched with the idea that institutions have an important role to play in the creation and diffusion of new knowledge and in the process of growth, even if it is difficult to establish ex ante the nature of these relations. Thus in the paper, I focus on scientific and technological knowledge and its relationship with human capital, on the issue of open science and the necessary setting of appropriate institutions for knowledge creation. 8 Moreover, I examine OECD data related to investment in knowledge in OECD countries, with particular attention to human capital, to evaluate their economic performances, and I underline the need of a long term growth policy for the EU economies consistent with the Lisbon Agenda. Conclusions end up the paper. 1. Knowledge and Human Capital Knowledge is a basic resource for the economy and it has been historically at the heart of the process of economic growth. Scientific and technological knowledge, in particular, is of key importance for the growth, and also knowledge about how to organize and manage economic activities is crucial to determine the performance of economies and of firms. The economic historian Joel Mokyr (2002) has ably described the way in which the accumulation of knowledge has transformed the western economies into modern economies based on knowledge. Mokyr highlights the importance of “useful knowledge” for the economic growth, that is, «the beliefs people hold about their physical milieu». ... «The effective deployment of that knowledge, scientific or otherwise, in the service of production is the primary – if not the only – cause for the rapid growth of western economies in the past centuries »1. He suggests that the change in the rate and nature of economic growth must be explained through developments in the intellectual realm concerning this “useful knowledge”. Therefore, societies are richer since they “know” more. This means that the social knowledge, defined as the union of all pieces of individual knowledge, has expanded. However, the creation of useful knowledge is a necessary but not sufficient condition for the growth, since a variety of mechanisms to reduce access costs must be found and, hence, appropriate institutional changes must be carried out to make those mechanisms effective. 1 Mokyr (2002), p. 19. 9 If the creation of knowledge is a cumulative enterprise and is strongly affected by the information exchange, nevertheless knowledge must not identified with information. Scholars of technological change have challenged the view that information and knowledge should be considered as synonymous, by arguing that this view is inadequate for understanding the process of technology transfer. Knowledge is fundamentally a matter of cognitive capability2, since it empowers its possessors with the capacity for intellectual and physical action. According to Leydesdorff (2006), knowledge enables us to codify the meaning of information; thus, it enables us to discard some meanings and to retain others. Moreover, knowledge itself can be codified, although the codification of knowledge works imperfectly. Information, instead, consists of structured and formatted data that remain inert until used by those with the knowledge needed to interpret and process them. Therefore, information is passive, static and discrete. Information and knowledge have also different costs of reproduction. While the cost of replicating information amounts to no more than the price of making copies (the marginal cost of copying is decreasing thanks to the adoption of ITCs), reproducing knowledge is a far more expansive process, because cognitive capabilities are not always easy to transfer to others and, in any case, they require learning and the mobilization of cognitive resources. But knowledge may not be codified and rests in implicit personal or institutional practices, often associated with craft-like skills, awareness of reputations and handson techniques. In this case we have tacit knowledge that cannot be reduced to conscious and codified methods and procedures. Tacit knowledge is naturally excludable, since it cannot be considered immediately and freely exploited. This tacit knowledge can be transferred by demonstration and by personal instructions, but in any case it cannot be assimilated to information3. Moderns economies, which are knowledge based, are characterized by an explosion of data and codified knowledge, propelled by a revolution in information and communication 2 3 Foray (2004), p. 4. Polanyi (1966); Cowan, David and Foray (2000). 10 technologies (ITCs)4. ITCs, in fact, are considered general purpose technologies5, so the demand for them tend to be elastic; furthermore, they are networking technologies, which favours integration. The process of globalization is also characterising the economies today and this process is creating a stronger integration of markets and a major role for knowledge. The global economy is actually based on knowledge, skills, learning and innovations mainly produced by R&D, and globalization has become more pervasive just because it is driven by the use of ITCs. It is possible to distinguish two conceptual frameworks concerning knowledge-driven economies6. One is the framework that emphasizes the ‘scientization of technology’, stressing the key roles of R&D, ITCs, ‘high-tech’ industries and the knowledge economy. In this theoretical framework the massive growth of externalities associated with scientific knowledge affects the large sector of science-based industries. Firms belonging to this type of industries share scientific and technological parameters, including intellectual understandings concerning technical functions, use of materials, performance characteristics and so on. The increasing power of absorptive capabilities of firms plays a critical role here. Thus, large communities of ‘intelligent agents’ combined with an intensive use of new ITCs are likely to make the marginal costs of reproducing, transmitting and acquiring knowledge fall dramatically. The knowledge economy is, therefore, an economy in which knowledge externalities are more powerful than ever due to the double trend of ITC development and increasing investments in education. Another conceptual framework, that can be called the ‘engineering-based’, stresses the key role of design and craftsmanship and focuses on lower tech and more established industries and sectors. According to this second framework, networks and ITCs will reinforce the existing configurative 4 In 2001 the ITC sector represented 10% of business value added in the OECD area. OECD (2005), p. 10. 5 Helpman (1998). 6 Smith (2002); Thompson (2004). 11 production environment and enhance its potential productivity gains rather than displace it with a completely new paradigm of production. In particular, the role of ITCs is to create better conditions to communicate between network participants, thus, to complement the ‘handshakes’ rather than substitute for them. Therefore, if we consider the ‘engineering-based’ framework, the emphasis would shift towards considering a complex combination of forms of production that do not ignore the tacit, craft-based and design-led aspects of the present production environment. The two different conceptual frameworks outlined above don’t need to be considered mutually exclusive. First, there are important feedbacks coming from the engineering techniques and practical experience that produce scientific and technological innovation. Second, since knowledge becomes central for producing goods and also services, we experience complementary forms of production, which has been historically kept divided. So craft production based on tacit knowledge reassumes importance, but also lean production and flexible specialization are typical forms in these economies founded on knowledge and innovation. Even aspects of mass production still remain important in industries like biotechnologies, ITCs, and others associated with natural sciences, that have been experiencing high rates of growth. In modern economies, technology is knowledge (Mokyr, 2005b), and knowledge, despite it is difficult to handle, is at the core of modern economic growth. Then, economic growth is possible if there is a sustained technological progress. In knowledge-based economies new technologies are deeply changing the economic structure and contributing to productivity increases. Neoclassical theory of innovation and growth in its more recent literature considers knowledge production and technological progress to be simply a function of rational and purposeful application of research and development (R&D), and of accumulation of complementary physical and human capital. But R&D covers only a small part of all innovation and knowledge production activities. Innovation is a process that involves a break from past familiar practice; it also implies a considerable uncertainty about how to make the new 12 practice work effectively. The innovative activity requires sophisticated learning by doing and using, and is characterized by high risk of failure, as well as a major payoff from success. These aspects of innovation are not considered enough by mainstream economic literature7. Moreover, following Mokyr, David, Nelson et al., a theory of innovation and growth based on knowledge creation and diffusion and on technological progress needs also to consider the institutional factors that allow knowledge to be applied and become profitable. These institutional factors such as the intellectual property rights, the operation of a well functioning labour market, the efficiency of the credit system, the relationship between firms and universities, the community-networks of scientists, the quality of intellectual property rights system, become complementary to technological progress and knowledge creation and must change with them. Therefore, the institutional environment is also crucial for the long run growth. In the following part of this section, I stress the importance of human capital, in particular of education and instruction, since human capital can be acquired through formal schooling and on-thejob training, emphasizing its central role for knowledge creation and its effects on the long run growth. The growth and productivity differentials among countries, which are empirically observed, depend essentially on the capability of improving the quality of human capital and of immaterial factors of production, and the capability of improving these un-tangibles assets seem to depend on the creation and the transfer of new knowledge and new ideas. Thus, human capital is important for the diffusion of new knowledge, and its endowment and its quality is essential for the growth. The relevance of human capital has been already pointed out by Adam Smith, who interpreted human capital as skills, dexterity 7 Nelson (2005), p. 26. Metcalfe (2002) stresses, instead, the relevance of the demand side of innovation, emphasizing the micro-diversity of behaviours and the link between the process of creativity and the formulation of novelty by consumers and firms. 13 (physical and intellectual) and judgement8. A consequence of this view is that societies with a better endowment of human capital are considered to have a greater development potential than societies with scarce or inadequate human resources. Moreover, improving the quality of human capital has another important policy implication: upgrading the knowledge and the skills of human capital facilitate not only higher level of production, but can also determine a less badly skewed distribution of income. Despite the wide agreement among the economists on the fact that human capital is an important determinant of economic growth, there is little consensus on the exact contribution of different measures and indicators of human capital to economic development and on how the passage from human capital endowment to economic growth is achieved9. However, there is a widespread literature of models that postulate a relation between the high quality of human capital and total productivity, so the quality of human capital becomes essential for the growth. In short, the long run growth of a knowledge-driven economy depends on the quality of its human capital and on the capacity of matching its educational supply with labour demand, which tends to become more sophisticated; in fact, human capital and technology have a complex relation, which is difficult to predict. EU economies, for instance, have shown in the last decade wide differences in the growth rates; this outcome can be partly due to the role of human capital. In several empirical studies, it has become evident the significancy of the quality of human capital with respect to the evolution of technology, of job satisfaction, of 8 Since Smith the term of human capital was used by Marx, but the best-known application of the idea of human capital in economics is that of the Chicago School of economics. In particular, Becker’s Human Capital (1964) became a standard reference for many years. In Becker’s view human capital is similar to physical means of production; one can invest in human capital (via education, training, medical treatment), so one’s output depend partly on the rate of return on the human capital one owns. More recently, Lucas (1988) has demonstrated that the growth of human capital is a permanent source of economic development. 9 For a critical survey on human capital measurement and its effects on growth see Helpman (2004, chps. 4 and 5). 14 matching educational supply and local labour needs, and also of migration. More likely, to have a correct assessment of the quality of human capital, rather than a measure of educational stock or any accumulation indicators, it is important to take into account some indicators of the quality of the education provided, as a measure (number or percentage) of high school students, of university graduates, of post-graduates and doctorates, and a measure of employment of high graduate people. In conclusion, the relationship between knowledge and human capital is essential for growth. Mokyr thinks, in fact, that the advances in knowledge and their capability to improve the human lot is critical to material progress10, even if the growth of knowledge alone is not a sufficient condition and it needs an environment in which knowledge can be put at work. To make this possible Mokyr takes into consideration human capital, with its knowledge and competences11. He thinks human capital important for the growth, because it reduces access costs: the marginal cost involved in acquiring knowledge possessed by someone else in society. But progress in knowledge and human capital, although important, are not enough to allow a long term and sustained growth, it is also necessary to have an appropriate institutional environment which must allow the spreading of knowledge, and institutional changes that complement the knowledge systems, which, in turn, follow an evolutionary path. In the following section I examine the issue of ‘open knowledge’ in knowledge-driven economies, analyzing also the role of economic and political institutions, with the aim to explain and underline why institutions matter. 10 Mokyr (2005a), p. 33. Mokyr defines ‘competence’ the knowledge needed to execute a technique. Competence consists of the knowledge how to read, interpret, and execute the instructions in the technique and the supplemental tacit knowledge that cannot fully written down in the technique’s codified instructions. (2005b), p. 1120. 11 15 2. Institutions matter: the issue of ‘open knowledge’ Although knowledge is a public good in the sense that the consumption of one does not reduce that of others, the private costs of acquiring it are not negligible; thus, exploiting the existing stock of knowledge will depend on the efficiency and cost of access to knowledge. When the access costs become very high, the social knowledge tends to disappear. Mokyr (2005b) argues that the determinants of these access costs are both institutional and technological. «”Open knowledge” societies, in which new discoveries are published as soon as they are made and in which new inventions are placed in the public domain through the patenting system (even if their application may be legally restricted), are societies in which access costs will be lower than in societies in which the knowledge is kept secret or confined to a small group of insiders. ... As access costs fells in the early modern period, it became more difficult to maintain intellectual property rights through high access costs, and new institutions that provided incentives for innovators became necessary...»12. Therefore in Mokyr’s view economic institutions (i.e. laws to protect property rights, a well functioning relationship between firms and universities) are necessary to stimulate the accumulation of knowledge and its application to the development of new technologies. He also thinks that is important to have appropriate political institutions to provide the ‘right’ environment to make the innovation activity possible. David (2007), in turn, identifies in the ‘open science’ a basic feature of the modern knowledge societies. An essential characteristic of this ‘open science’ is its public, collective character, and its commitment to cooperative inquiry and free sharing of knowledge13. Moreover, openness reduces duplication and fosters spillover effects. The ethos of the ‘open science’ is supported by an institutional infrastructure, that is, a constellation of differentiated institutions shaping the conduct of scientific and technological research. David is firmly convinced that the idea for public 12 13 Mokyr (2005b), p. 1119. David (2007), p. 6. 16 universities to help support themselves financially by owing and exploiting intellectual property is a bad idea14. Therefore, he is against the proposal of the emerging “entrepreneurial university”, especially in Europe. He thinks, in fact, that institutions are influenced by past history, so they are path dependent; then Europe must be aware of its past and, at the same time, find suitable institutional innovations, considering reforms that build upon the region’s own rich and diverse institutional foundations to promote economic growth. Already Dasgupta and David (1994) carried out a fundamental analysis of open knowledge, where they offered an explanation for the prevalence of distinct norms, customs and institutions governing university scientific knowledge, on the one hand, and industrial R&D, on the other. Dasgupta and David concentrate on rules of priority and the role of validated priority claims in the reward structure of academic scientists, and also on the institutions associated with scientific communication. One of their main propositions is that there are no economic forces that operate automatically to maintain dynamic efficiency in the interaction between university-based open science and commercial R&D. Thus they warn that the dependence of knowledge-based industrial development upon the science-technology nexus must not be transformed into a regime of “universally privatised science”15. Also Nelson (2004) criticizes the idea of a science that tend to become extensively privatized, since science base largely is the product of publicly funded research, and the knowledge produced by that research is and must remain open and available for potential innovators to use16. He makes clear that the theoretical position about open scientific knowledge must be defended and that to privatize basic knowledge is a danger both for the advance of science and for the advance of technology. Nelson stresses that technological advance is an evolutionary process, thus there are great advantages of having multiple paths explored by a number of different actors. 14 David (2005), p. 168. Dasgupta and David (1994), p. 515. 16 Nelson (2004), p. 455. 15 17 From his perspective the fact that most of scientific knowledge is open is extremely important: many individuals and firms can use the scientific knowledge they need in order to compete intelligently in this evolutionary process17. The analysis of the theories of these economists show that the emergence of institutions and the need of institutional change become crucial to keep “open knowledge” societies and to sustain growth. Thus institutions matter and this is one of the main proposition of those who do not accept the traditional neoclassical view, because it leaves out institutions from its analysis. Douglas North (1990), in particular, believes that institutions constitute the fundamental explanation of economic growth, rather than factors of accumulation and innovation, which are necessary but no sufficient conditions for the growth. In North’s view institutions are the rules of the game that guide the conducts of the organizations and govern the evolution of their behaviours. The wide and recent economic literature on institutions has demonstrated that the institutional infrastructure is crucial to determine the incentives to innovation and to influence the development of new technologies and the organization of production, it also affects the degree of competition within an industry, the flows of information between the industries and the organizations that produce new technological knowledge (Universities, Research Agencies), the incentives to accumulation of physical and human capital and it concurs to improve the quality of human capital as well18. Institutions create the external environment in which organizations and individuals operate, reducing the uncertainty, but they must be reliable, produce stability, and be able to adapt themselves to the changing environment, if they want to guide the process of knowledge creation and to promote the long run growth19. In the next section a descriptive analysis at macroeconomic level is put forth that focuses on investment in knowledge in the 17 Nelson (2004), p. 460. Mokyr (2002). For a critical discussion of the recent economic literature on institutions: Helpman (2004), chp.7. 19 Schilirò (2004), pp. 41-42. 18 18 OECD countries to evaluate their economic performances, emphasizing the role of human capital and of institutional education (i.e. the universities). Moreover, I underline the need of a long term growth policy for the EU economies suggesting some proposals consistent with the Lisbon Agenda. 3. Investing in knowledge: performances and policies for the growth On the whole, the OECD economies are based on knowledge and information. It is estimated that over 50 per cent of Gross Domestic Product in the major OECD economies is now knowledge-based. In its recent Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard OECD20 has produced many indicators and statistics, focusing on investment in knowledge, which comprises expenditure on R&D, public spending on higher education, and software21. The theoretical framework implicitly assumed by OECD is that of a knowledge economy, characterized by science-based industries, which emphasizes the scientization of technology and the role of globalization. Investment in knowledge in the OECD area reached around 5,2% of GDP in 2002, compared to around 6,9% for investment in machinery and equipment. If expenditure for all levels of education were included, investment in knowledge would be in excess of 9% of GDP for the OECD area22. A theoretical reading of these data can suggest that investment in knowledge increases the productive capacity of the other factors of production and also transforms them into new products and processes. Moreover, knowledge can spill over from one industry to another or from one firm to another, with new ideas used repeatedly at little extra cost. Such spillover can ease the constraints placed on growth by scarcity of capital or other 20 OECD (2005). The data for each country are usually referred to years 2002-2003, but in some cases are referred to previous years (back to 1999). 21 Software is a global, young and dynamic industry, which employs about 2 million of workers just in Europe. Software as a commodity is complementary to other investments and it is an input to the production of many products and services. 22 OECD (2005), p. 14. 19 factors (i.e. energy). Since knowledge investment is characterized by increasing returns, it becomes the main engine of long-term economic growth. Hence, sustained increases in innovative investment can lead to continuous improvements of economic performance and to rise a country’s growth rate. This latter proposition is confirmed by Furman and Hayes (2005), who maintain, through their empirical analysis and qualitative assessment, that economies such as South Korea, Ireland and Finland have succeeded in becoming innovative and economic growth leaders because in the 1980s and in the 1990s they have continuously increased their investments in R&D and human capital over time and also raised their commitments to innovation-supporting policies23. Considering the main OECD macro-areas, the United States invests most in knowledge (6,6%) followed by Japan (5,0%) and the European Union (3,8%). The ratio of investment in knowledge to GDP in 2002 varied from 1,8% (Portugal) to 6,8% (Sweden) across OECD countries, see Table A. The share was lowest in southern European countries (Italy is among them with a share of 2,3%) and highest in Nordic Countries, South Korea and United States. These data are also consistent with the empirical results of Furman and Hayes on emerging countries. One of the components of the investment in knowledge is R&D expenditure. Actually, R&D expenditure is one of the two indicators (the other is R&D personnel) to measure the resources allocated by a country to R&D efforts. OECD defines R&D as creative work undertaken on a systematic basis in order to increase the stock of knowledge, including knowledge of man, culture and society, and the use of this stock of knowledge to devise new applications. Yet, the OECD’s definition of R&D contains some deficiency; in particular it does not 23 Furman and Hayes (2005), p. 197. Furman and Hayes examine a panel dataset of 23 countries between 1978 and 1999. They focus on the emerging innovator countries to analyse the factors of their success in catching up to the world’s leader innovator countries. 20 take fully into account tacit knowledge24, which is the main informal source of innovations especially for the small and medium firms, as it is the case of Italy, where the industrial sector is constituted mainly by a multitude of small and medium firms that are organized in industrial districts. Therefore, the following figures must be interpreted with a pinch of salt. Table A Table B, instead, shows the R&D intensity, which is given by R&D expenditure relative to GDP, for the OECD countries in 2003. 24 Tacit knowledge cannot be reduced to codified methods and procedures, but it is an important source of new products and new processes. Cowan, David and Foray (2000). 21 In particular, in Japan and European Union the R&D intensity has increased steadily over the past years. Although EU (15) is below United States and Japan. In 2003, Sweden, Finland, Japan and Iceland were the only four OECD countries in which R&D intensity exceeded 3%, well above the OECD average of 2,2%. The shortfall in Europe’s relative R&D expenditure level vis-à-vis Japan and U.S is not the lower rate of public sector research investment, but, rather, the comparative shortfall in private business investment in R&D as proportion of GDP. Table B R & D intensity, 2003 22 Knowledge-based economies are also strongly influenced by the quality of human capital. There is a significant and positive correlation between quality of education at university level and economic performance. The countries with the best universities are usually those that have a better innovative capacity and the highest rates of growth25. Paul David has significantly identified the university as the institution suited to meet the critical needs (research and innovation) for the knowledge-driven economic growth26. An important specific indicator of the investment in knowledge is represented by the flows of university graduates. The higher education system is indeed the main source of human resources in science and technology. This human capital variable, considered by the OECD Scoreboard and referred to university graduates, represents the country’s potential for assimilating, developing and diffusing knowledge and supplying the labour market with highly skilled workers. In 2002, for instance, OECD universities awarded some 5.9 million degrees at university level, of which 156000 doctorates. Finland and Australia had the highest graduation rates at university level (over 45% of the population )27. Moreover, about one-third of university graduates obtain a degree in the social sciences, business and law. Science-related studies (excluding health and welfare) are the second most popular field of study, with one OECD graduate in four obtaining a science and engineering (S&E) degree. United States and European Union outflows of university graduates represent some 32% and 39% of total OECD university degrees respectively. EU higher education systems deliver more advanced research and S&E diplomas. In 2002, European universities granted 532000 S&E university degrees, which is 42% of total OECD university degrees awarded in these fields, compared to only 23% for 25 The universities currently fulfil three primary functions: a) the development of highly qualified human resources; b) the accomplishment of R&D activities; c) the synergistic relationship with the surrounding society, through the public use of the scientific and technological potential of the university. 26 David (2005). 27 OECD (2005), p. 46. 23 the United States. The gap widens for doctoral degrees: European universities awarded 55% of all S&E doctorates. This evidence demonstrates that Europe is a leader actor in the world scene for qualifying human capital in scientific and engineering knowledge28. Another significant indicator of the quality and upgrading of human capital and of the labour market’s innovative potential is the employment of tertiary level graduates. Investments in human capital and, in particular, in education have led in many countries to a rise in educational attainment, which is also reflected in the composition of employment. More specifically, the employment of scientists and engineers is an important mechanism for effecting knowledge transfers that bring economically valuable spillovers to the commercial R&D sector29. On average, 28% of persons employed in the OECD area had a tertiary-level degree in 2003. Canada and Japan (over 40%) and the United States (38%) ranked far ahead of the European Union, where less than one worker out of four holds a tertiary-level degree. But Europe shows large cross-countries disparities: Finland, Belgium and Sweden tertiary-level graduates account for more than a third of employment, whereas Portugal, Italy and Slovak Republic account for less than 15%. A third relevant indicator concerning human capital and specifically the human resources allocated to R&D is the number of researchers employed. Researchers are viewed as the central element of the R&D system: they are defined as professionals engaged in the conception and creation of new knowledge, products, processes, methods and systems and are directly involved in the management of projects. In 2003, approximately 3.4 million researchers were engaged in R&D in the OECD area. This corresponds to about 6.6 researchers per 1000 employees, a significant increase from 1995 level of 5.6 per 100030. 28 Of course, there are wide differences among European countries and among European regions. 29 Dasgupta and David (1994), p. 511. 30 OECD (2005), pp. 60-61. For those countries that compile data by qualification only, data on university graduates employed in R&D are used as a proxy. 24 Among the major OECD regions, Japan has the highest number researchers relative to total employment, followed by United States and the European Union. Anyway, 38% of all OECD area researchers reside in the United States, 29% resides in the EU15 and 19% in Japan. In the major economic areas, the share of business researchers in the national total differs widely. In the United States, four out of five researchers work in the business sector but only one out of two in the European Union. The analysis of these OECD statistics confirms that education is at base of the development of human capital since it constitutes the legacy of one generation to the following one. Winning countries and regions, in fact, have a much better stock of education. Moreover, the acquisition of knowledge is strongly related to the institutional education and, for the higher education, to the role of the universities. By providing higher education a country can contribute with this policy to foster the competitiveness and economic performance of industries, firms and regions and also to attract companies from other countries. The contribution of education is not only via improvements the quality of the workforce and the formation of managerial expertise, but also via innovation with the diffusion of new processes and new products, because of the dynamic links and feedbacks between educational level, learning activity and advances in technology. Therefore, improving education has a long-run and permanent effect on the economic growth rate. To sum up, the data on R&D expenditures and on investment in human capital, specifically in tertiary education, would seem to show that Europe, with the exception of the Nordic countries, had a weaker performance and lagged behind United States, Japan and some emerging countries (i.e. South Korea) in the recent past. This has been largely a consequence of weaknesses of several EU countries in the crucial technological fields that characterize the contemporary knowledge-based economy. A relevant view, based on a theoretical approach more close to mainstream economics, is that of Zilibotti (2008), who argues, by 25 analyzing a number of empirical applications of his growth model of imitation and innovation using OECD data31, that economies, which fail to introduce economic reforms as they grow, may become stuck in non-convergence traps. In other words, they grow without developing. This happens because the evolution of the institutional environment (i.e. contractual arrangements that adapt to the changing needs of technological progress) is neither necessary nor serendipitous, but it is subject to high uncertainty and path dependence. Then, institutional change must be pursued with appropriate policies. The foregoing analysis brings me to suggest that to overcome the weaknesses which characterize the European economy on the whole, it is necessary to pursue a set of policies consistent with the Lisbon strategy that brings Europe on a virtuous path of long run growth. Especially nowadays when the emergence of high growing economies, like China, South Korea, India, Russia, etc., sets a new stage of global competition. Empirical and theoretical economic studies have widely shown that EU economies can significantly grow if the accumulation of knowledge is enhanced. To make this target feasible it is necessary to have higher investment in R&D. But, following David (2005), Europe can achieve this aim through the creation of new institutions that will provide the organizational infrastructure, complementary to its universities and institutions of higher education, to foster the production of knowledge and, hence, the generation of commercially successful science-based innovations, whose results are built upon publicly supported research. Higher ITC investments are also necessary, since knowledge-based economies are strongly influenced by the transmission and diffusion of knowledge. Europe must create the conditions to have a stronger impact of technology diffusion, then low access costs, as Mokyr (2005b) maintains, are a fundamental condition to facilitate it. Furthermore, EU economies must be sustained to upgrade their human capital with higher investment in education and instruction, 31 Zilibotti considers in his model either physical-capital investment and firm-specific human-capital investments (2008, pp. 331-332). 26 and to increase their share of employment of the best qualified individuals. Europe must achieve a deeper integration of markets ( especially in the service sector), and it must be able to possess suitable institutions that improve the regulatory environment. In general, institutions, according to Mokyr, must co-evolve with technological change, so institutional change becomes a necessary condition to guarantee the growth in the long run. But it is also important to realize that there is no a unique correspondence between the functions that good institutions perform and the form that such institutions take. Finally, in several EU economies (i.e. France, Italy, Portugal) small and medium firms characterize the industry, this type of firms usually follow the engineering-based framework of production, where a complex combination of forms of production that do not ignore the tacit, craft-based and design-led aspects often give content to the process of creativity that mark their products. So it is necessary an innovation policy aimed to help specifically these type of firms with measures like fiscal and credit facilities, but also with an institutional infrastructure as an organized system, in terms of legislation, operational conducts, research partnerships with the university-industry-government infrastructures aimed to knowledge production and technology transfer. All these policy proposals might help Europe to overcome its present situation of relative low growth pushing it on the virtuous path of a stable long run growth, coherently with the Lisbon strategy. Conclusions This paper, following a Schumpeterian view that looks at the modern economic growth as a knowledge-driven process, has focused on knowledge, human capital and institutions to explain the process of long run economic growth of modern industrial economies, which are increasingly becoming knowledge-based, that is, economic systems founded on high levels of investment in knowledge, which imply investment in education, research and development, software and information systems. Moreover, the paper 27 tries to suggest some proposals for a long term growth policy of the EU economies consistent with the Lisbon Agenda. In the first section, the relationship between knowledge and human capital is analysed. Since the diffusion of technological knowledge requires sophisticated learning, the transfer of knowledge needs high quality of human capital and, hence, a good education system to increase the productivity of the economy, more than the accumulation of human capital endowment. Moreover, two frameworks related to the knowledge-based economies are identified. The first one focuses on the scientization of technology and stresses the role of R&D, codified knowledge, ITCs and high-tech industries. The second framework focuses on an engineering approach and stresses the relevance of tacit knowledge, of craft-based and designled aspects of production and on lower tech and more established industries. In both frameworks the quality of human capital is crucial to acquire and transfer knowledge. In this paper an important place has been given to the analysis of ‘open knowledge’ and its effects on growth, and the consequent necessary setting of appropriate institutions. Following Mokyr, David, et al., a theory of growth must be based on a system of ‘open knowledge’ that favours knowledge creation and diffusion and the development of technological progress, but this view implies the need to consider institutions, and it requires necessary changes in the institutional environment. Finally, I have analyzed the performance of knowledge economies in the OECD area giving a descriptive analysis and showing some significant data related to expenses in R&D, investment in human capital and employment of tertiary-level graduates in OECD countries. The descriptive analysis of OECD data demonstrates that countries’ development is directly related to their continuous investments in education and R&D, and that qualified university graduates constitute a country’s basic source for developing and diffusing knowledge. Moreover, some policy proposals have been suggested that might help Europe to reach and go along a virtuous path of long run growth, consistently with the Lisbon strategy. 28 References M. Abramovitz - P.A. David (1996), Technological Change, Intangible Investments and Growth in the Knowledge-Based Economy: The U.S. Historical Experience, in D. Foray - B.A. Lundvall (eds.), Employment and Growth in the Knowledge-Based Economy, OECD, Paris 1996, pp.35 - 60. D. Acemoglou - S. Johnson - J. Robinson (2005), Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth, in P. Aghion - S.N. Durlauf, Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1A, Elsevier, Amsterdam, 2005, pp. 385-472. G.S. Becker (1964), Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. R. Cowan - P.A. David - D. Foray (2000), The Explicit Economics of Knowledge Codification and Tacitness, «Industrial and Corporate Change», vol. 9, n. 2, pp. 211-253. P. Dasgupta - P.A. David (1994), Towards a New Economics of Science, «Research Policy», vol. 23, pp. 487-521. P.A. David (2005), New Science, New Industry and New Institutions? Second Thoughts on Innovation and European Universities, in A. Quadrio Curzio - M. Fortis (eds.), Research and Technological Innovation, Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, 2005, pp. 151-173. P.A. David (2007), The Historical Origins of ‘Open Science’, Working paper, Stanford University, Economics Dept. June, pp. 182. P.A. David - D. Foray (2003), Economic Fundamentals of the Knowledge Society, «Policy Futures in Education. An e-Journal», January, pp. 1-22. D. Foray - B.A. Lundvall (eds.) (1996), Employment and Growth in the Knowledge-Based Economy, OECD, Paris 1996. D. Foray (2004), The Economics of Knowledge, The MIT Press, Cambridge (Mass). J.L. Furman - R. Hayes (2005), Catching up or standing still? National innovative productivity among ‘follower’ countries, 29 1978-1999, in G.D. Santangelo (ed.), Technological Change and Economic Catch Up: The Role of Science and Multinationals, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham 2005, pp. 171-211. E. Helpman (1998), General Purpose Technologies and Economic Growth, MIT Press, Cambridge (Mass.). E. Helpman (2004), The Mistery of Economic Growth, Harvard University Press, Cambridge (Mass.). L. Leydesdorff (2006), The Knowledge-Based Economy: Modeled, Measured, Simulated, Universal Publishers, Boca Raton (Florida). R.E. Lucas (1988), On the Mechanism of Economic Development, «Journal of Monetary Economics», vol. 22, pp. 3-42. B.A. Lundvall (2003), Why The New Economy is a Learning Economy, «Economia e politica industriale», n. 117, pp. 173-185. J.S. Metcalfe (2002), Knowledge of Growth and Growth of Knowledge, «Journal of Evolutionary Economics», vol. 12, pp. 315. J. Mokyr (2002), The Gifts of Athena. Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy, Princeton University Press, Princeton. J. Mokyr (2005a), The Intellectual Origins of Modern Economic Growth, in A. Quadrio Curzio - M. Fortis (eds.), Research and Technological Innovation, Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, 2005, pp. 17-80. J. Mokyr (2005b), Long-Term Economic Growth and The History of Technology, in P. Aghion - S.N. Durlauf, Handbook of Economic Growth, vol.1B, Elsevier, Amsterdam, 2005, pp. 1113-1180. R.R. Nelson (1995), Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change, «Journal of Economic Literature», n. 1, pp. 4890. R.R. Nelson (2005), The Roles of Research in Universities and Public Labs in Economic Catch-Up, in G.D. Santangelo (ed.), Technological Change and Economic Catch Up: The Role of Science and Multinationals, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 19-32. D.C. North (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. OECD (1996), The Knowledge-Based Economies, OECD/GD (96) Paris 1996, pp. 1-46. 30 OECD (2005), Science, Technology and Innovation Scoreboard, Paris. M. Polanyi (1966), The Tacit Dimension, Doubleday, New York. D. Rodrik (1998), Symposium on Globalization in Perspective: An Introduction, «Journal of Economic Perspectives», vol. 12, n. 4, Fall, pp. 3-8. D. Schilirò (2004), Economia della conoscenza, dinamica strutturale e ruolo delle istituzioni, «Istituzioni e Sviluppo Economico», n. 3, 2004, pp. 27-49. J.A. Schumpeter (1912), Theorie der Wirtschaftlinchen Entiwicklung, Leipzig; trad. it., Teoria dello sviluppo economico, Sansoni, Firenze 1971. J.A. Schumpeter (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Harper, New York. K. Smith (2002), What is the Knowledge Economy? Knowledge Intensity and Distributed Knowledge Bases, United Nations University, «discussion paper # 2002-6», pp. 1-28. W.E. Steinmueller (2002), Knowledge-Based Economies and Information and Communication Technologies, «International Social Science Journal», vol. 54, pp. 141-153. G.F. Thompson (2004), Getting to Know the Knowledge Economy: ITCs, Networks and Governance, «Economic and Society»,vol. 33, November, pp. 562-582. F. Zilibotti (2008), Economic Growth through the Development Process, « CESifo Economic Studies » , vol. 54, n. 3, pp. 325-357. 31 CENTRO DI RICERCHE IN ANALISI ECONOMICA, ECONOMIA INTERNAZIONALE E SVILUPPO ECONOMICO Working Papers (*) 1994 Alberto Quadrio Curzio La Banca d’Italia dal 1914 al 1936 1994 Alberto Quadrio Curzio Tre livelli di governo per l’economia italiana 1994 Alberto Quadrio Curzio e Roberto Zoboli Linee di recente sviluppo dell’arco alpino ristretto 1994 Giuseppe Colangelo Optimal durability with buyer’s market power 1994 Giuseppe Colangelo Vertical organizational forms of firms 1994 Giuseppe Colangelo Exclusive dealing may foster cross-collusion 1994 Piergiovanna Natale Pricing strategies: a brief survey 1994 Piergiovanna Natale Posted vs. negotiated information prices under asymmetric 1994 Roberto Zoboli The Alps in the economic and ecological systems of Europe 1994 Daniela Feliziani (*) It is a new series of Cranec Working Papers, began in 1994. Since 1978 to 1994, 45 working papers have been published. 32 Organizzazione e regolamentazione degli orari di lavoro nei paesi industrializzati 1995 Maddalena Baitieri Sistemi di ricerca e innovazione tecnologica 1995 Maddalena Baitieri Sviluppo tecnologico e tutela dell’ambiente e della vita Piergiovanna Natale Rapporto di lavoro: una reimputazione 1995 1996 Alberto Quadrio Curzio e Fausta Pellizzari Risorse, prezzi e rendite ambientali. uniperiodale Un’analisi 1997 Alberto Quadrio Curzio Italy and the European Monetary Union. Why Italy is on the border line? 1998 Giulio Cainelli e Claudio Lupi The choice of the aggregation level in the estimation of quarterly national accounts 1999 Deborah Grbac Sulla globalizzazione del sistema economico con particolare riferimento all’economia lombarda e milanese 1999 Marco Fortis PMI, Distretti industriali e liberalizzazione del mercato dell’energia elettrica 2000 Deborah Grbac Transnational and inter-regional cooperation macroeconomic flows, a case-study. Mitteleuropea 2000 Alberto Quadrio Curzio Dalle istituzioni economiche continentali e sovranazionali. principio di sussidiarietà and nazionali a quelle Applicazioni del 33 2001 Floriana Cerniglia e Massimo Bordignon L’aritmetica del decentramento: devolution all’italiana e problemi connessi 2001 Fausta Pellizzari Environmental resources, prices and distribution 2001 Massimo Visconti Misure della performance d'impresa e indicatori di bilancio: un paradigma ancora valido? 2001 Marco Fortis e Alberto Nodari Un marchio di qualità AVR per la produzione italiana di rubinetteria e valvolame: uno strumento per la valorizzazione e la promozione del made in Italy Floriana Cerniglia Distributive politics and federations 2002 2003 Floriana Cerniglia La riforma del titolo V della Costituzione e i nuovi rapporti finanziari fra Stato ed autonomie locali: una valutazione quantitativa 2003 Floriana Cerniglia Decentralization in the public sector: quantitative aspects in federal ad unitary countries 2003 Giuseppe Colangelo, Gianmaria Martini Relazioni verticali e determinazione del prezzo nella distribuzione di carburanti in Italia 2003 Floriana Cerniglia (con M. Bordignon e F. Revelli) In search of yardstick competition: a spatial analisys of Italian municipality property tax setting 2003 Alberto Quadrio Curzio Europa: crescita, costruzione e Costituzione, Working Paper Cranec-Diseis (Dipartimento di economia internazionale, delle istituzioni e dello sviluppo) 34 Working Papers edited by Vita&Pensiero (**) 2003 Daniele Schilirò Teorie circolari e teorie verticali della dinamica economica strutturale: verso uno schema analitico di carattere generale 2003 Fausta Pellizzari Esternalità ed efficienza. Un’analisi multisettoriale 2003 Alberto Quadrio Curzio Europa: crescita, costruzione e costituzione 2003 Fausta Pellizzari Regolamentazione diretta e indiretta in un modello multisettoriale 2004 Mario A. Maggioni e Teodora E. Uberti La geo-economia del cyberspazio. Globalizzazione reale e globalizzazione digitale 2004 Moshe Syrquin Globalization: too Much or is too Little? 2005 Giovanni Marseguerra Il “capitalismo familiare” nell’era globale: la Sussidiarietà al servizio dello Sviluppo 2005 Daniele Schilirò Economia della Conoscenza, Dinamica Strutturale e Ruolo delle Istituzioni 2005 Valeria Miceli (**) This new series of Cranec Working Papers began in Autumn 2003 with the cooperation of the Catholic University Editor, Vita&Pensiero. 35 Agricultural Trade Liberalization and the WTO Doha Round 2005 Valeria Miceli EU Agricultural Policy: the Concept Multifunctionality and Value Added Agriculture of 2006 Floriana Cerniglia La spesa pubblica in Italia: articolazioni, dinamica e un confronto con altri Paesi 2006 Mario Nosvelli Distretti e tecnologia: il caso di Lumezzane 2006 Monica Carminati La legislazione italiana e regionale sui distretti industriale: situazione ed evoluzione 2007 Letizia Romeo Le fondazioni di sviluppo: una realtà con un forte potenziale 2007 Daniele Schilirò Knowledge, Learning, Networks and Performance of Firms in Knowledge-Based Economies 2008 Rosario La Rosa Infrastrutture e sviluppo. Premesse per un’analisi del settore turistico in Sicilia 2008 Francesco Salsano – Teodora Erika Uberti I sistemi elettorali e la politica fiscale: il caso italiano dal 1861 ai giorni nostri 2008 Fausta Pellizzari Scarcity, Innovation and Sustainability 36 2008 Daniele Schilirò I Distretti Industriali in Italia quale Modello di Sviluppo Locale: Aspetti Evolutivi, Potenzialità e Criticità 37 finitodistampare.qxp 23/01/2009 8.40 Pagina 1 Finito di stampare nel mese di novembre 2008 da Gi&Gi srl - Triuggio (MI) Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore CENTRO DI RICERCHE IN ANALISI ECONOMICA E SVILUPPO ECONOMICO INTERNAZIONALE Investing in Knowledge: Knowledge, Human Capital and Institutions for the Long Run Growth Daniele Schilirò ISBN 978-88-343-1790-7 € 3,00